I wonder what the children they raise would be like.

The following are excerpts from the book "A Generation of Sociopaths How the Baby Boomers Betrayed America" by Bruce Cannon Gibney

Keep in mind that "boomer" is specific to a generation of americans, and does not nessicarily apply to europeans, though I think the UK may have some of these issues as well.

CHAPTER ONE

THE VIEW FROM 1946

Happiness is like the pox. Catch it too soon,
and it wrecks your constitution.

—Gustave Flaubert1

Exactly when Flaubert caught the pox was unclear—he definitely had it by twenty-eight, after a sojurn to the fleshpots of Beirut—but what his biographers make abundantly clear is that his first three decades were miserable.2 While Flaubert’s youth was frustrated, it did lead to triumphs like Madame Bovary. Unlike Flaubert, the Boomers were happy from the start and this conditioned them to believe effortless, affluent contentment was their due, and they behaved accordingly. One might wish that the Boomers had been a little less happy then, so the rest of America could be substantially more happy today.

But happy Boomers would be; they could not be otherwise. They were, after all, the human instantiations of American optimism. Convention dates the Boom to 1946, though it started as early as 1940, when the Depression fully lifted and Americans were enthusiastic about the future. The Boom continued until the mid-1960s, delivering the largest American generation ever seen. Even under the narrowest definition, the Boom produced about seventy-five million new Americans and more than ninety million measured over the full stretch between 1940 and 1964, increasing the population by roughly half.*,4

The Boom

Boomers are products of more than mere chronology, however. They can be identified by their shared experiences, their generationally unique behaviors and beliefs, and by what they gave to America, what they took, and what they still hope to get.

The United States of the 1950s was wealthy, powerful, and expanding quickly, and if the young Boomers didn’t acquaint themselves with the national income tables, they could certainly see growth all around them. They only had to look at the flags they saluted in their new classrooms, duly updated to reflect the statehoods of Alaska and Hawaii in 1959. The present middle age of diminishing expectations lay decades ahead—the long stagnation of the new millennium, the chronic debts and erosion of the middle class, the vanishing species and melting ice caps, the reach of terrorism into the homeland and the shambolic Middle Eastern empire it provoked—these were unimagined, indeed, unimaginable. Those disasters required a certain generation to summon them, and that generation was just rolling off the production line.

Thanks to the competent stewardship of prior generations—a mix of the Greatest Generation, the earlier Silents, and a few nineteenth-century fossils—the optimism that led to the Boom in the first place found seemingly endless confirmation in American success. In the three decades following World War II, it would have been ridiculous to pose the question, as Ronald Reagan would when seeking the presidency in 1980, “Are you better off [now] than you were four years ago?”5 The answer was “yes,” always and emphatically. The Boomers’ first decades saw rapid and near-continuous gains in prosperity, education, health, technology, and civil justice, the products of revolutionary choices by earlier generations, underwritten by their saving and sacrifice.

Even the 1970s, the supposedly dismal era in which many Boomers reached adulthood, weren’t that bad; in economic terms, they were better for many workers than the past decade has been. Factually, if not rhetorically, the answer to Reagan’s question in 1979–1980 was no worse than “mostly better.” As we’ll see, a swaddled youth fostered sociopathic entitlement, and the temporary setbacks of the 1970s provoked a generational tantrum from which we have yet to recover. But that’s getting ahead of the story.

Happier Days

The Boomers suffered virtually nothing of the Depression that shaped their parents and, unlike their European peers, did not have to confront the suffering and guilt that marked Europe for decades after the war. With the exception of Pearl Harbor, where 2,471 Americans died, the homeland escaped the war basically unscathed. Japanese subs blew up an oil derrick and destroyed a baseball field in Oregon, and the Empire dispossessed America of a few Alaskan islands for a time, and that was about it. A childish mind might have been inclined to view one of the greatest of wars as something of a game.

Just as the United States survived the war intact, so did most of its families. American casualties were relatively low, some 405,399 killed and 670,846 wounded out of a population in 1945 of about 140 million, a casualty rate of well under 1 percent, with few civilian deaths.6 War deaths for Germany, Japan, the Soviet Union, and the United Kingdom stood vastly higher—at least six times higher in the case of Japan and fifty times higher in the Soviet Union, which had to battle famine, internal strife, and the Wehrmacht.7 By V-E Day, Dresden and Hamburg had been reduced to rubble; by V-J Day, Nagasaki and Hiroshima had been wiped off the map. In 1945, ash blew off the ruined hulks on Berlin’s Unter den Linden and settled on corpses. On Manhattan’s Fifth Avenue, ticker tape drifted down from balconies and landed on the shoulders of soldiers kissing strangers.

If the Boomers took a different path than their American parents or their European and Asian contemporaries, a path that eschewed social solidarity in favor of personal indulgence, it was in substantial part because Boomers started from a radically different place. Boomers have always thought of themselves as Special, and nothing about their childhoods provided any evidence to the contrary. Any illusions pre-Boomers had about easy lives had been dispatched by the Depression and the actual fighting of the World Wars; the Boomers suffered none of these. The oldest Boomers might have been lightly touched by want, but American rationing was comparatively moderate and short-lived. If the greatest of wars couldn’t restrain American consumption, Boomers might reason, what could? (The sociopath might add, what should?)

By contrast, the United Kingdom’s restrictions on sugar and meat finally lapsed in 1953–54 and could have been only a modest consolation for the humiliating evaporation of empire then underway. The Soviet Union was afflicted by hunger, death, and tyranny for years. And the British and the Soviets were victors; those who lost faced even greater ruin. The destruction of Japanese cities is well known, but devastation even reached the countryside, which had been denuded of trees because the army had dug up all the pine roots to make gasoline substitute. The Germans, meanwhile, had been firebombed and were starving, reduced to eating the few zoo animals air raids hadn’t killed. Even after the bodies were buried and the cities mostly rebuilt, the legacy dragged on: Non-American belligerents were still paying off some war debt and debating old claims well into the twenty-first century.

For the young Boomers, Tragedy was for Over There, privation for Others. Europe and Asia would have to work hard to overcome tragedies of epic proportions, and they built functional and caring societies—imperfect, to be sure, but radically better than what had come before. The Boomers, living a different life, took a different course.

Durable Goods

Having won the war in 1945, America had to figure out what to do with the peace, and it embarked on a course that would eventually provide tremendous direct and indirect benefits to the Boomers. The most pressing postwar question was that of a labor market swollen with newly unemployed soldiers. It was a problem after every major war, one America had not always resolved successfully. After the Civil War, benefits paperwork was wrapped in actual red tape, which probably says it all about the speed and liberality of veterans’ programs in the nineteenth century.

After World War II, the United States decided on a course of generosity and foresight, one that might have served as an inspiration for later challenges, had the Boomers been apt pupils. The Servicemen’s Readjustment Act of 1944 (the GI Bill) provided veterans with a range of benefits including tuition and living expenses for education, unemployment insurance, and low-cost loans for housing and to start businesses. Congress supplemented the GI Bill after the Korean War, providing further funding to the same general ends. Because the bills were not tested against class or origin, they tremendously improved economic equality, although in the early years the boons skewed overwhelmingly toward white men because of biased implementation, the lack of integrated educational institutions, and prohibitions on women’s service in the armed forces. Even that would change. In the meantime, millions of (mostly white, male) people who otherwise never could have attended college did so, enjoying the benefits of education at minor personal expense. The creation of a large, well-educated, prosperous middle class, where position could be earned rather than inherited, was in large part a result of programs like the GI Bill and civilian educational grants. These helped the Boomers’ parents earn and pass down wealth, and would help the Boomers themselves avoid the sort of crippling debt they forced their own children to incur.

After a brief war in Korea, peace prevailed, and in the 1950s President Dwight Eisenhower set about building much of the national infrastructure on which the United States still depends, systems the Boomers have cheerfully neglected. Eisenhower had seen the problems bad infrastructure created and what good infrastructure could do. In 1919, he led a cross-country convoy that managed a meager 6 mph across roads and bridges ranging from partially built to nonexistent. In the 1940s, Eisenhower appreciated the virtues of modern infrastructure on tour in Germany, a nation crisscrossed with the Reichsautobahn, where Volkswagens designed by Ferdinand Porsche (founder of the eponymous company) could trundle along with considerably greater efficiency—Adolf Hitler had mandated 100 kph, ten times faster than Eisenhower’s 1919 convoy had managed.

Eisenhower demanded American autobahnen and got them. Construction of the Interstate Highway System (IHS) began in 1956 and concluded in 1991, fifty thousand miles in all, carrying about a third of the nation’s traffic. Since then, the IHS and other midcentury infrastructure projects have been decaying, victims of Boomer neglect. But during its heyday, America had the best infrastructure in the world, especially the roads that opened up the country and made possible the Boomers’ comfortable suburban childhoods.

Those childhoods, taking place in homes at the end of Eisenhower’s asphalt arteries, were exceedingly comfortable. Indeed, homes were so good that when Richard Nixon unveiled a typical example at the American National Exhibition in Moscow in 1959, the Soviets refused to believe such prosperity could exist. For them it was ranch house à la Potemkin, a fraud in clapboard and shag. The Soviet propaganda arm TASS opined that there was “no more truth in showing this as the typical home of an American worker, than, say in showing the Taj Mahal as the typical home of a Bombay textile worker.”8

TASS was wrong. The Exhibition’s show home was not only realistic, it was more or less real, being a copy of 398 Townline Road of Commack, Long Island, a three-bedroom house furnished by Macy’s. The original 398 Townline cost $13,000, somewhat below the average price of homes at the time, readily affordable at about 2.5 times the era’s $5,400 family income.9 (Today, Zillow values 398 Townline Road, which still stands, at about $420,000 or about six times 2015 family income.10) It would have been pointless to inform the Soviets that this beige box was only the smallest taste of wonders to come.

Two years before the Exhibition, the Soviets had undertaken a demonstration of their own system’s merits, launching a twenty-three-inch metal ball into orbit. Generally called Sputnik, the satellite’s proper name was Простейший Спутник, or “Elementary Satellite,” and it was elementary indeed, carrying no scientific instruments, only a radio. Instruments were superfluous to the primary mission, which was to beat Americans into orbit, which Sputnik did.

America responded by investing heavily, creating NASA and the Advanced Research Projects Agency (now DARPA) to prepare new technological wonders to humble the Soviets. The government also quadrupled funding for the National Science Foundation, beginning a long period of sustained and lavish grants to science and technology. The National Defense Education Act of 1958 supplemented the GI Bill, pouring money into colleges, with particular emphasis on producing more scientists and engineers. The combined effect of these educational policies increased college enrollment from about 1.5 million in 1940 to over 3.6 million in 1960 and 8 million in 1970 (or in percentage terms for college-age populations, from 9.1 percent to 22.3 percent and then 32.6 percent).11 The United States may have started slightly behind in the Space Race, but by 1958 it had satellites in orbit doing real science and handling communications traffic. America’s second satellite collected geodetic data and orbits still; Sputnik and its Soviet creators have vanished. All of these programs would confer enormous benefits on the Boomers, at a cost disproportionately borne by their parents—a pattern the Boomers inverted and then inflicted on their own children.

These investments became the self-reinforcing engine of prosperity, and the national account books made clear the degree to which they succeeded. After a brief postwar dip, the economy grew robustly. Despite the transition to a peacetime economy, unemployment was often under 4 percent and not persistent (as unemployment is today), despite large numbers of Boomers entering the workforce.12

Americans under fifty might wish for the litany of midcentury accomplishments to run out, since the inescapable comparisons with the era of Boomer policies are so utterly disheartening, but the list continues—and it’s just as well, because Americans still rely on the work done long ago, like the GPS developed for the military from the 1960s, the Internet developed by ARPA, and the integrated circuit from Jack Kilby’s work for the Army and Texas Instruments. Even the power for these technologies depends on a grid developed from the 1930s through the 1960s, itself supplied by dams (now rotting) built during the Great Depression and reactors (now ancient) pioneered in the late 1950s, as part of Eisenhower’s Atoms for Peace program. Washington’s goal was “electricity too cheap to meter,” provided by fission and then (hopefully) fusion, built by American ingenuity and, in the case of the versatile nuclear contractor American Machine & Foundry, the nation’s leading supplier of bowling equipment (it was the Fifties).13 All that relentless investment in human capital, energy, science, and infrastructure spurred growth whose gains translated into rapidly rising incomes. The Fifties are no more distant or irrelevant than your iPhone, which is charged by power distributed over a midcentury grid and depends on government-sponsored research on GPS, the Internet, and the integrated circuit.

Decay would be the Boomers’ project; midcentury America had room only for progress, for more and faster. And just as the economy was modernizing, so was society. While the 1950s exist in the popular imagination as a time of stifling conformity, as static as the shellacked hairdos of its suburban matrons, they were actually a time of great social change. Legacy preferences, racial restrictions, Jewish quotas, and other systems that had perpetuated the old order began giving way to more merit-based criteria, while generous subsidies ensured that admissions offers were more than notional promises. Colleges may not have been as diverse as they are now in absolute terms, but the midcentury revolution in admissions makes today’s affirmative action (partly eroded by Boomer courts and legislatures) seem timid.

Having supplied adults with college degrees, jobs, roads, and homes, all of great but sometimes indirect benefit to the Boomers, the nation began to care expressly for its newest citizens—a debt the Boomers never seriously considered repaying. The shambolic educational system that existed before the Depression was reformed and generously funded. The federal government bankrolled junior colleges and expanded vocational training from the 1940s through the 1960s, and both the states and Washington committed themselves to building world-class universities.

In 1965, the federal government decided to extend aid all the way down to primary education, supplemented by income assistance to poorer families to feed and clothe children that they might make the most of opportunities educational and otherwise. The Elementary and Secondary Education Act provided federal funds to schools serving lower-income populations, helping equalize achievement gaps.14 It was a generous and open-hearted plan, sufficiently groundbreaking that conservatives questioned its very constitutionality.

Justice for Some Becomes Justice for Many

Before the 1940s, segregation had been an ironclad fact. After the war, Harry S. Truman integrated the army and arguments for its civilian equivalent became hard to ignore. In 1954, the Supreme Court took a chance to reverse an 1896 ruling, and found that separate was not equal.15 The great revolution in rights then beggars the Boomers’ achievements in this department, a subject we will resume in Chapter 16. The passage of the Voting Rights Act of 1965 also advanced equality, helping black votes, previously diminished by racial regulation, count for the same as white. The pattern of federal intervention to avoid racist abuses was therefore established early in the Boomers’ childhoods. Government protection became the default; the recent rollback under Boomer Supreme Court Justices is perhaps less “conservative” than is presented.

So that was the cradle, circa 1965—free and integrating public education, good universities and substantial financial aid, decent and plentiful jobs, quality infrastructure and good homes—what about the grave? That question was addressed in the New Deal by Social Security and in the Great Society by Medicare.

At the time it was conceived in the 1930s, Social Security was a program for the relatively small number of very old retirees. The official name of the legislation was the “Old-Age, Survivors and Disability Act,” which hinted at the rather limited category of people that legislators expected would collect. Life expectancy in the 1930s was just over sixty-five years and benefits kicked in, perhaps not coincidentally, around the same time.*,16 The demographic data meant that old age benefits were originally designed for the catastrophe of extreme age, rather than nearly universal assistance to cushion years and then decades of retirement. Those who did collect were often in severe need, as elderly populations in prior decades were particularly prone to poverty (a situation that no longer applies today, when elderly poverty is quite low while youth poverty remains quite high). From the 1930s onward, the state guaranteed against disaster.

In 1966, Medicare debuted, providing funds for senior health care, so the elderly were supplied with both a modest income and a certain minimum level of medical care and insurance against catastrophic illness. As part of the Great Society and the War on Poverty, funds were also extended regardless of age to poor populations for both health care and income assistance—welfare, in short.

So, the bulk of what we think of as the social safety net was therefore in place by 1966, along with growing protections to ensure that classes of people other than comfortable whites could participate, at least in a partial way, in national prosperity and politics. For mainstream Boomers, childhood through early adult years shared the important commonality that things were both good and getting better; in the event circumstance or chance put prosperity out of reach, the state would ensure that individuals could only fall so far. This was even the case for blacks, who experienced the largest and fastest gains in equality since the Civil War and Reconstruction, though progress was uneven and often marked by violence.

These conditions were all provided for by the Boomers’ elders, who worked and saved to ensure that the fiscal house was in reasonable order when it was passed down. Doing so required older generations to tax themselves at rates that no politician today, however far Left, would dare propose. When possible, it was pay as you go, so unlike more recent wars, the Korean War was substantially financed out of current tax receipts, as were many of the great infrastructure projects, whose costs were overwhelmingly borne by earlier generations even though later generations would reap so much of their benefit. In cases where no level of tax could balance the budget, as was the case with World War II, prior generations retired the debt as quickly as possible. Motivated by fiscal probity, Americans paid extraordinary taxes for two decades, with the highest marginal rate a downright confiscatory 94 percent in 1945 (against which today’s 39.6 percent, the source of so much present angst, seems modest).17

The result of these sacrifices was that, by the 1960s, World War II debt had been reduced to a manageable size. Taxes could therefore be lowered, though the top rate remained a hefty 70 percent.18 Although the Vietnam War eroded the nation’s financial position, things were still in relatively good shape in 1970. As a percent of GDP, the deficit was –0.3 percent and the national debt 35.7 percent; modest, compared to –2.5 percent and 103.8 percent, respectively in 2015.*,19 Fiscal affairs were not perfect, but they were strong, especially considering the enormous investments built up after the war, and in vastly better order than they will be when the Boomers pass the books on to their children. The Boomers inherited a productive family farm with a modest mortgage; in twenty years, their children will take over a crumbling estate leveraged to the hilt.

Thus, the psychology of the Boomers formed during a period of America ascendant, master of the world and even, by 1969, of the moon. As the Boomers reached adulthood, they inherited a richly endowed and functional society, one that, despite some flaws, protected and provided for the Boomers better than it had for any preceding generation. And yet, the Boomers emerged as radicalized adults, rejecting so many of the policies that had given them so much, replacing a successful model with an antisocial failure.

Inheritances as large as those the Boomers received can have warping effects, as the unemployable trust-fund set whizzing down the slopes of St. Moritz shows. (The Boomer electorate has recently furnished a more domestic example.) Still, prosperity tends to be a boon overall, and worth risking. So what went wrong with the Boomers? Had other, less desirable factors contributed to a rising class of suburban sociopaths?

There were, because the standards by which the Boomers had been raised were, by historical standards, downright bizarre.

CHAPTER TWO

BRINGING UP BOOMER

The little, or almost insensible impressions on our tender
infancies, have very important and lasting consequences.

—John Locke, Some Thoughts Concerning Education1

As all Freudians know, analysis begins with childhood, that rich swamp from which adulthood’s good and evil spring. This is not to say that humans are consigned to perform a deterministic play written by childhood, only that the formative years are just so: a period in which operating assumptions and other habits of mind form. For a generation later associated with individualism, the Boomers had surprisingly uniform childhoods, at least in the white middle class that then accounted for the plurality of the population. Though the methods used to rear the Boomers might have been uniform within that generation, they were strikingly distinct from child rearing practiced on other generations. The Boomers’ upbringings were dominated by a new set of influences, chiefly permissive parenting, bottle-feeding, and television. If the Boomers grew up to be so different from any generation before them, it was perhaps because they had been raised unlike any prior generation; if they remain generationally unique, it is perhaps because some aspects of their childhoods have never quite been repeated.

The popular television show Leave It to Beaver, which debuted in 1957, provides a fair portrait of Boomer childhood. The show’s utter lack of imagination was both its artistic vice and sociological virtue. Compared to today’s operatic contrivances and reality television, Beaver was pure anthropological rigor. The subjects of study, the Cleaver family, were studiously unremarkable: two parents (Ward and June), two kids (the Beav and Wally; presumably the statistically required fractional additional child would have been unsettling to display), plunked down in a suburban house enclosed, inevitably, by a white picket fence. Ward was a World War II veteran who had attended a state college, presumably on the GI Bill, and worked at a trust company; June ran the house. The Cleaver children were both Boomers, notionally born in 1944 and 1950, and raised in ways that would have been instantly familiar to their peers on the other side of the set—and alien to their grandparents. For above all, Ward was a soft touch, a sharp contrast to his own father, an ancien régime monster of discipline and corporal punishment.

Childrearing: Dawn of Time—AD 1946

If the oldest Cleaver’s methods shock now, that was not the case for most of human history. Grandpa Cleaver’s methods were those by which children had long been raised. The old system was not without its grim logic. Because of high infant mortality—even in the nineteenth century, it was not uncommon for 20 percent of children to die before age five—parents saw no reason to invest substantial material or emotional resources until it was clear a child would live. Should a child survive, parents would set themselves not to the arrangement of playdates and other diversions, but to the production of a miniature grown-up, conformed to adult notions of virtue and industry, ready for near-immediate employment. Dialogue with children was unnecessary and motivation best supplied by the stick.

Even more enlightened approaches, which began appearing in the seventeenth century, were unforgiving. John Locke, famous now as the expositor of the social contract (something the Boomers would gleefully rip up), was more renowned in his time as a child-care expert. Locke’s Some Thoughts Concerning Education (1693), progressive as it was, inclined toward discipline (a word appearing an average of twice a page in my version of Thoughts).* Locke’s goal had been to produce “virtuous, useful, and able men” by the “easiest, shortest, and likeliest means,” and that certainly did not entail pampering of the kind the Boomers received.2 The behaviorists of late-nineteenth-century America, whose thinking dominated the rearing of the Greatest Generation, shared Locke’s goals. They had only to look at the country industrializing around them to know how Locke’s seventeenth-century process might be improved. Locke’s character-forming exercises, which depended on weird exercises involving leaky shoes and hard beds, were too haphazard for the modern world. Henceforth, good children would be manufactured by a rationalized process of positive and negative reinforcement, delivered immediately, and unburdened by Locke’s philosophical meanderings about human nature. In 1899, “less sentimentality and more spanking” was the order of the day, according to G. Stanley Hall, president of Clark University, psychologist, and child-care authority. If children didn’t like it, that was beside the point. One did not ask a widget whether it approved of the means of its production. Why should children be different?

Like Hall, Dr. Luther Emmett Holt of Columbia University favored the scientific rearing of children, and his views enjoyed enormous influence. Holt’s The Care and Feeding of Children (1894) was a best seller, eventually repackaged by the Government Printing Office and widely distributed as a sort of state-sanctioned guide for child care. Like factory workers and farm animals, children were not to be indulged—they were to be managed. While the specifics of these behaviorist texts differed from prior practice, the central insights about child care remained the same until the 1940s: Children were to be formed according to their parents’ wishes and society’s needs, with parenting a matter of coercing useful behaviors, instead of catering to childish whims. Given the bottomless thrift, industry, and manners of the Greatest Generation, perhaps these ideas weren’t meritless so much as victims of excessive zeal.

Dr. Spock and the Rise of Permissive Parenting

Unstable or erratic parenting, or inconsistent parental discipline may increase the likelihood that [childhood] conduct disorder will evolve into antisocial personality disorder.

—DSM-V3

Rigor was therefore the dominant practice for American children until Benjamin Spock changed things in an instant. Spock was, like Locke, a trained physician, with a specialty in pediatrics. With the assistance of his wife, he produced The Common Sense Book of Baby and Child Care, first published in 1946, in time to guide Boomer upbringings. A best seller of tremendous proportions, it sold five hundred thousand copies in its first six months, and in the half century following its printing, was surpassed only by the Bible in sales (or so the story goes).4 A contemporary poll of American mothers showed that 64 percent had read Spock’s book, and even those who didn’t own a copy couldn’t help but absorb its precepts; excerpts cropped up everywhere, with snippets even appearing on I Love Lucy and implicit in Beaver.5 The defining text of Boomer youth came from Dr. Spock, not Jack Kerouac or Robert Pirsig.

The Common Sense Book treated every imaginable topic, but its core injunctions were always the same: that parents rely on their own instincts and accommodate children’s needs wherever reasonable. In a radical departure, the Common Sense Book even strove to comprehend a child’s worldview from the perspective of the child himself, a task conservatives viewed with apprehension. In the preface, Spock stated that his “main purpose in writing [his] book was to help parents get along and understand what their children’s drives are.”6 Older traditions could not have cared less about understanding a child’s motivations.

Unlike his predecessors, Spock did have psychological training, and he disdained the old fixation on discipline and distance, instead emphasizing loving care, physical affection, and a degree of deference to a child’s impulses. His attitude toward toilet training is instructive. Previously, experts advised a regimented approach, with children to be trained at three months (one wonders how) and evacuations taking place on a set schedule, Taylorism for tots. This, Spock believed, was an exercise both destined to fail and that risked the development of certain neurotic compunctions, like an anal-retentive personality overly fixated on tidiness and orderliness, though likely to be productive and deferential to authority (e.g., the Greatest Generation). Instead, Spock encouraged parents to let children set their own defecatory timetable, a system not without its own dangers. Freud had warned that indulgent toilet training could lead to an anal-expulsive personality, one that proceeded from literal to figurative incontinence, personalities of messiness, disorder, and rebelliousness (e.g., the Boomers).

Part of Spock’s relative leniency came from his radically optimistic views on human nature, his belief that children would grow up well so long as their parents provided a good example. Spock wrote that “discipline, good behavior and pleasant manner… You can’t drill these into a child from the outside in a hundred years. The desire to get along with other people happily and considerately develops within [the child] as part of the unfolding of his nature, provided he grows up with loving, self-respecting parents.”7 Two thousand years of parenting experts would have disagreed; parents most definitely could drill habits into a child, with the notion of relying on a child’s good nature to achieve the desired results being the very definition of insanity.

Cultural conservatives predicted that America would collapse in lockstep with discipline’s decline, and they were not entirely wrong. Norman Vincent Peale, a preacher famous for writing The Power of Positive Thinking, characterized Spock’s method of child rearing as “feed ’em whatever they want, don’t let them cry, instant gratification of needs.”8 Peale blamed Spock for helping create the culture of permissiveness in the Sixties, and he was not alone, though Peale and other critics failed to consider Spock’s text as a whole. The Common Sense Book did allow for spanking as a last resort—it just preferred to deploy gentler options first. Still, in missing these nuances, the conservatives might have proved their point. Spock’s book was not supposed to be read front to back like a novel, but topically, like a guidebook, consulted to resolve a particular problem on a particular day. To the extent this structure made it possible for parents to overlook a few admonitions about laxness, Peale was inadvertently correct.

The Bottle-Fed Baby Boom

There were few subjects on which Spock did not have definite opinions, many of them for the better, but on two critical subjects Spock harbored ambivalence with far-reaching and negative consequences. The first was breast-feeding, which for obvious reasons, has been the standard mode for infant nutrition for almost the entire human experience. Spock had always promoted breast-feeding, but until 1968 remained very open to using formula as an acceptable substitute. Between the convenience of formula and Spock’s permission, Americans turned to the bottle in droves. So for one brief period in history, which overlapped almost perfectly with the Boomers’ childhoods, bottle largely replaced breast.

By the 1970s, research emerged suggesting that breast-feeding conferred important advantages that formula did not. Studies confirm that breast-feeding positively impacts cognitive development/intelligence, significantly reduces the risk of diabetes, childhood obesity, and other illness, promotes better health in the mother, and strengthens emotional bonds between mother and child.9 (In some of these areas, Boomers have struggled, as we will later see, though the bottle was not entirely to blame.) Influenced by these revelations, rates of breast-feeding quickly rose and now compare to those of a century ago, with only poorer, less educated, and certain minority groups still relying heavily on the bottle. But no entire generation of children before or since was so influenced by formula, and in nutrition, as they were in so many other ways, Boomers were unique.*,10

From Bottle to Boob Tube

The other major area where Spock gave some very bad advice regarded that other great influence on Boomers, television. Older Americans perceive the arrival of computers and the Internet as sudden and pervasive, but these newer technologies have nothing on television, adopted at astonishing speed and scale. RCA began mass production of televisions in 1946. Before then, almost no American homes had televisions. By 1960, 90 percent had TV. In contrast, the first Internet connections were established in 1969, but access didn’t become a household staple until the late 1990s, and even by 2012, more than a quarter of American households still lacked a broadband connection.11

Not only did television reach more homes more quickly than the Internet, use was very intense from the start. The degree of American preference for television appears most vividly measured as a percentage of leisure hours, because when given the choice, Americans greatly prefer TV. Data compiled in 2015 shows that TV consumed more than 50 percent of Americans’ free time, against just 13 percent for socializing and functionally 0 percent for pleasure reading (e.g., for teenagers, 8 minutes per weekend day).12 In a very serious way, from the Boomers’ childhoods onward, TV is what Americans do. Leaving aside for now the considerable body of research showing that television negatively affects childhood development, reasonable people can immediately see the problem: It’s just not healthy to spend the majority of one’s free time immobilized in front of the box.

However, when TV first arrived, it was greeted as just another miraculous appliance, an innocuous electronic nanny. The first mass-market set arrived the same year as Spock’s book, which was understandably silent on the issue. However, Spock had a generally permissive attitude toward radio, saying that children could listen to it as much as they liked, so long as it didn’t detract from sleep, homework, and outside play. In later editions, Spock said the same of television, remaining unconcerned all the way through the late 1960s both about the amount of TV children consumed and its content.13 The Boomers therefore were not only the first televisual generation, but the only one whose relationship with the box was unmediated by the cloud of expert concern, parental reservation, content chips, and so forth that later swirled around TV. Like the Windsors’ mistresses, TV was a defiling enticement, one to which the Boomers were helplessly susceptible and would constantly return.

Early criticism devoted itself to TV’s aesthetic deficits, but the real problem has never been one of art, but of medium. Unlike media that came before, television is at once ironic, mimetic, unidirectional, emotionally rich, informationally poor, highly habituating, and demands a certain suspension of disbelief.* These characteristics prevail regardless of whether a given show is elevating or crude, a news program or a cartoon, and the effects have not been good. While the many studies of TV have occurred over decades in which programming varied widely, the consensus has always been the same—always negative.

TV’s essential characteristics make it the perfect education for sociopaths, facilitating deceit, acquisitiveness, intransigence, and validating a worldview only loosely tethered to reality. As a breeding ground for dissembling, television almost cannot help itself, because unlike older media, it inherently operates on a minimum of two levels, the visual and audio, sometimes supplemented by a third level of text. These concurrent streams make it easier to achieve multiple meanings, allowing for divergences between what is said, what is seen, and what is meant. Televisual irony trains viewers to hold otherwise inconsistent views simultaneously, and it is no coincidence that in an era where TV is the most profound cultural influence, the trend has been from earnest to ironic. It’s not that television makes lying easier per se, but that television encourages a layered approach to reality in ways that other media do not. Television therefore serves as a training and reinforcement mechanism for deceit, a key trait of the sociopath. The televisual-sociopathic apex probably arrived in Seinfeld/Curb Your Enthusiasm, both created by Boomer Larry David. David’s shows were outliers only in their brilliance; in their sociopathic aspect they were just the culmination of preexisting trends.

Television is also mimetic, spurring viewers to imitate behaviors seen on-screen, and the behaviors the industry wants to foster are consumptive. There’s plenty of dense academic literature on this subject, but nothing speaks louder than the enormous ad budgets devoted to TV, stoking the already robust sociopathic appetite. At least parents today understand the dynamic, and since the late 1970s, with the introduction of affordable VCRs and purchasable content like DVDs and downloads, they have been able to reduce or eliminate the number of conventional ads their children see (somewhat undone by the rise of product placement). Young Boomers could not even resort to the commercial-free uplift of public television, because PBS didn’t debut until 1970, and its public predecessor offered just ten hours of weekly programming.

Given that people spend more than twice as many hours watching TV than they do socializing, TV sets the tone for all communication, and that tone is unidirectional, the conveyance of opinion rather than the mutuality of conversation. The box speaks one way to the audience, and the people inside the box often speak past each other; it’s soliloquy, not dialogue. Though there were some early attempts at serious conversation, TV proved an infertile medium. No later than the 1960s, the modern style of televisual dialogue had been established. During the 1968 Republican National Convention, the ABC network sponsored debates between William F. Buckley and Gore Vidal, icons of the Right and Left respectively. Despite a gap of five decades, the Buckley/Vidal sessions would in their generalities be immediately familiar—two celebrities screeching at each other. Strip away the bad ties and the polysyllables (a final hangover from the empire of the written word) and the modern shouting match emerges fully formed, one that devolved into Vidal characterizing Buckley as a “crypto-Nazi” and Buckley returning the favor by calling Vidal a “queer” and threatening to “sock [Vidal] in the goddamn face.”14 These were bad debates, but “good TV.” Unfortunately, the standards of television leaked out of the box and into real life, serving to disfavor the sorts of exchanges that might promote learning and compromise, major challenges for the Boomers.

One of the redeeming features of Buckley/Vidal was that it featured two people who, however ill behaved in the moment, were intelligent expositors of genuinely different points of view on matters of substance (rather than, say, two different points of view on a starlet’s outfit at the Oscars). Early in TV’s history, networks felt obliged to present controversial issues like the ones featured in Buckley/Vidal in a fair and balanced way (in the original legal sense, not the Fox News sense). The FCC enshrined this ideal in the Fairness Doctrine, enacted in 1949.15 By 1974, the FCC found that it had never had to enforce it because broadcasters had voluntarily complied with the “spirit” of the rule; that’s not to say the networks were saints, only that they made modest gestures toward balance.16

By the 1980s, as Boomers achieved political power, broadcasters were freed to dispense with even the modicum of balance that guilt previously induced them to provide. In 1987, FCC chairman Marc Fowler—himself a (Canadian variety) Boomer, and so oblivious that he dismissed TV as “a toaster, with pictures”—formally abolished the Fairness Doctrine.17 The elimination of the Doctrine permitted the rise of ideologically driven channels, preaching to their respective choirs, a project completed in the 1990s when Fox News and MSNBC were disgorged by their parent companies. Dialogue became diatribe aimed at an agreeable audience in the same period that Boomers consolidated their control of governments. Boomers, who were adults by this time and also the heaviest consumers of news programming, therefore spent many hours with a device that would not challenge their worldviews.

It’s not as if other media were paragons of sensible debate, but no other medium could compete with the sheer number of hours Americans spent with TV nor the box’s special powers. Even if television were the acme of fairness, it would still be a uniquely limited and emotional medium, manipulating the cruder parts of the brain with musical cues so as to keep the cortex untaxed, flitting from image to image, and otherwise radically unsuited to rational thought (we will see some results in Chapter 5). Moreover, to enjoy many programs, one must literally reject reality: struggling waiters in Brooklyn do not live in giant lofts, fornicating with charming neighbors on Eames furniture. So for hours a day, people simply indulge in fantasy, forming habits that leak into other parts of life. (There’s probably a doctoral dissertation in the movie Poltergeist alone, its vaporous antagonist manipulating a child directly through her TV.)

TV’s limits pose special problems when it comes to news programming, and this is a grave problem for Boomers who, along with other (even older) Americans, are unusually dependent on TV’s witless reportage. Television operates at a distinct disadvantage to print—adults can read about twice as many words per minute as news anchors typically speak, and this does not account for the various commercials, empty banter, and other substance-free filler that consume a third or more of the average broadcast. Television isn’t kind to facts and even less so to nuance. Causation may run both ways, but the fact is that people who watch commercial broadcast TV news are significantly unrepresented in the category of people highly knowledgeable on matters of current events, the mechanics of government, etc.18

The warping effects of all these problems, from the collapse of the Fairness Doctrine to the limitations of TV and its presentation of the news, could be seen in the Boomers’ avatar Donald Trump. Like many of his generation, Trump relies heavily on TV news, and expects his preferred channels to cater to him first and reality second (if at all). When even the hermetic world of Fox proved insufficiently fawning, Trump tried with some success to conform the news to his preexisting conceits. The spectacle of The Donald bullying Fox in the crudest terms alarmed certain audiences, but after the Fairness Doctrine collapsed, that event was exceptional only in that an individual informed a network of his preferences directly, rather than the network divining those preferences through the inexact map of ratings.

Television, therefore, is a disastrous influence in purely theoretical terms; what about in practice? As an empirical matter, it’s hard to evaluate the full consequences of television, because it’s now essentially impossible to run a controlled study. Such a study would require a population of TV viewers to be compared against an otherwise representative group that did not watch television, and in a country where over 90 percent of households have long had TV and watch it several hours a day, that is simply impossible. America harbors no lost tribe of appliance-less Midwesterners, watching shadow puppets on the wall and waiting for sociologists to discover them.

But, for a time, Canada did conceal its own troupe of televisual Neanderthals, and these were the subject of the only major controlled study of TV’s consequences. It came about purely as the result of geographic accident. One town, whose identity was concealed behind the joking name of “Notel,” nestled in a valley that mostly blocked the local broadcast transmitter. Notel therefore did not receive effective TV coverage until years after surrounding communities did; Notel was otherwise similar to the two control towns, which did have TV.19

Adjusting for other variables like IQ, researchers found that Notel’s younger children scored higher on various tests, including reading comprehension and creativity.20 After TV arrived in Notel, scores declined to levels of other TV communities and researchers concluded, among other things, that “the weight of our evidence indicates there is a significant negative relationship between reading achievement and amount of television watched, even after IQ is controlled.”21 Notel’s children also became more aggressive after TV arrived, and TV might have exacerbated performance differences between more intelligent students and richer students and those who were less so.22 Effects in some categories were weak, and in other areas strong, but the overall effect of TV was decidedly disturbing. Eventually, children tended to converge toward the same levels of performance as they got older, but TV seemed to slow acquisition of important skills and have some hangover effects, and of course once children were older, the “No” had vanished from “Notel.”23

Even if we can no longer study large communities without TV, it is still at least possible to study differences between light and heavy viewers. These tests reveal a similar dynamic, “relatively strong negative correlations between viewing and achievement.”24 Reading comprehension and math performance all suffer when TV viewing is relatively heavy; children who watch a lot of TV are also more aggressive than light watchers (regardless of whether the programs themselves are especially violent).25 In 1980, newspapers widely circulated the conclusion of the California Superintendent of Schools: “Television is not an asset and ought to be turned off.”26

Needless to say, the superintendent has never gotten his wish—TV use remains high, and the greatest consumers of TV remain the Boomers, the generation most inclined to view TV as a “necessity” (a status ascribed to TV by about two-thirds of Boomers and their elders and by less than half for younger cohorts).27 It’s not that other generations don’t have their own issues with television, and the effects of newer media like immersive video games, smartphones, and Facebook will not be clear for some time. They are also beside the point for now, because it will be years before younger generations run the country. The unavoidable fact is that the nation is currently run by people who have a deep and unshakable relationship with TV, entranced from their beginnings by a medium with unambiguously negative effects on personality and accomplishment.

All of these factors, the shift to more progressive parenting, baby formula, and television, had effects that manifested by the mid-1960s. Studies repeatedly show that more permissive parenting styles produce lower performance in schools, make children more susceptible to peer pressure, and more likely to exhibit problem behaviors, though permissively raised children do have notably higher self-esteem than those raised in stricter households—a description that by now may sound familiar. That’s not to say authoritarian parenting avoids problems, as it produces, inter alia, higher levels of depression in girls and greater aggression in boys, but stricter parenting helps children achieve better self-regulation and higher achievement in schools.28

It is perhaps not surprising that Boomers’ test scores began sliding. Before they were even adults, Boomers were already failing. Constant SAT scores in both verbal and math categories slipped from 478 to 424 between 1964 and 1980; i.e., when the Boomers were taking these tests; once the Boomers graduated, test scores stabilized. We will take up this disturbing slide in Chapter 14. Boomers may have been wealthier and more secure than many test takers before or since, but they were less disciplined and had been raised in distinctly odd and unhelpful ways.

So that was the Boomers’ upbringing—televisual, formula fed, and above all, influenced by Dr. Spock and his new style of parenting. Those factors, along with the feelings of entitlement that postwar prosperity kindled, affected the entire generation, and the subset born between 1946 and 1955 perhaps most of all—and some of the Boom’s worst examples do seem to have been born in those years, as we’ll see. Nevertheless, these were only influences, not instructions. Some were negative and others were outright advantages. And however odd their upbringings, the Boomers were always free to choose—as they spent many years reminding the nation.

Many Boomers chose poorly, and those critics, like Norman Vincent Peale, who warned that the Boomers’ novel upbringings would lead to calamity, did not have to wait long for proof. It arrived the moment the Boomers became adults amid the turmoil of Vietnam. Unlike their parents, who faced a great challenge and left the world better for their participation, the Boomers confronted a minor conflict and found ways to make it substantially worse. The proof of Boomer sociopathy begins there and continues for the rest of the book.

CHAPTER THREE

VIETNAM AND THE EMERGING BOOMER IDENTITY

Among the calamities of war, may be justly numbered
the diminution of the love of truth, by the falsehoods
which interest dictates, and credulity encourages.

—Samuel Johnson1

No survey of the Boomers can be complete without revisiting the Vietnam War and its upheavals, which defined early adulthood for all save the youngest Boomers. The war began as a modest foreign intrigue in the Fifties, when the Boomers were children, and escalated into a genuine war from the mid-Sixties, just as older Boomers were becoming draft eligible. America withdrew in 1973 and South Vietnam collapsed in 1975, ending the war. America was desperate to move on, and President Jimmy Carter offered a wide pardon to draft avoiders in an attempt to close the book. Carter’s gambit failed to clear away the stench of strategic failure and domestic strife, and Vietnam still influences national life. Boomer Washington still strives to avoid “another Vietnam” even as it embroils itself in new quagmires. The politicians themselves cannot help but exhume Vietnam’s traumas. Anytime a man born in the 1940s or 1950s runs for office (Clinton, Kerry, McCain, Bush II, Bush-not-quite-III, Trump, etc.), the electorate must endure another parade of yellow draft documents and misinformation. Given Boomer longevity, Vietnam may linger for many years yet. Because of this, and the centrality of Vietnam to Boomer identity, it is important to understand Vietnam for what it actually was, rather than what the Boomers would have it be.

The Boomers are right about one thing: Vietnam was remarkable, though in unusual ways. In the usual ways, Vietnam was just a middling proxy war of middling strategic importance, of less consequence, and prosecuted with less mendacity and cruelty than other wars that are either forgotten or provoke no real anxiety. The Spanish-American, Mexican-American, and Native American wars were as bad as or worse than Vietnam, ranging from the fraudulent to the borderline genocidal. Status: forgotten. The Civil War, an existential crisis with horrific moral and constitutional dimensions, generates no mass hand-wringing; it’s even easy to drum up Confederate reenactors (try imagining Vietcong reenactors). World War II, of course, is generally seen as a “good war,” despite its considerable moral compromises, ranging from the indiscriminate bombing of civilian centers to the reduction of American citizens to internment camps. The Korean War, which was the closest analogue to Vietnam (Cold War proxy fight in Asia, indifferent conclusion, roughly similar fatality rates), lives on only in anodyne reruns of M*A*S*H. Even the conflicts in Iraq and Afghanistan, which have dragged on even longer than Vietnam and for purposes no more certain, occasion nothing like the angst of America’s Indochinese adventure. These latterly conflicts largely disappeared from the news even as they ground on; it’s easy to forget the United States remains involved. Why then all the strife about Vietnam—was it not, by war’s grim standards, nothing special?

The answer derives not from Vietnam’s strategic importance, which was never overwhelming; rather, Vietnam’s poisonous longevity arises in substantial part from the war’s entanglement with the other debates in the 1960s about civil rights, economic justice, personal freedoms and, more than anything, Boomer hypocrisy. Hindsight now allows many Boomers to recall an antiwar prescience they never actually possessed, of an unjust war prosecuted by old men over the objections of the young. A willful blindness about the mechanics of draft avoidance completes the whitewash, allowing many Boomers to characterize their escape from Vietnam as the mere exercise of an inconsequential administrative prerogative. Whether they see themselves as heroes or merely bystanders, the Boomers do not conceive of themselves as the authors of many of Vietnam’s misfortunes. The evidence shows something altogether less convenient for the Boomers, and therein lie the engines of Vietnam’s divisiveness. Vietnam triggers unease in America for the same reasons the Empire remains an uneasy subject for Britons: The moral failures of each stretched well beyond the Pentagon and Whitehall.

Guerrillas in the Mist

It’s been over forty years since the last American troops left Vietnam, and while the war continues to make itself felt as part of the dark matter of the American political universe, details have gotten fuzzy. For Americans who did live through the war, including all the Boomers, time erodes many details. Others facts have mutated or vanished entirely (e.g., the confusion surrounding the sincerity of B. Sanders’ application for conscientious objector status), lost to assiduous mythologizing like whitewashed draft histories (B. Clinton, D. Trump), misrepresentations by political opportunists (the Swift Boat ads that helped kill Kerry’s presidential bid); plain weirdness (Trump’s statements about John McCain being a loser for being captured); or in some cases, a simple refusal to discuss.2 For the rest, there are no memories to distort; over half of all Americans were born after the war and have no direct experience of it.3 The American history curriculum at public schools does little to inform these younger generations, and they know accordingly little about the conflict, though this doesn’t stop anyone from having feelings about Vietnam.*,4 So a brief recap seems in order.

While the Vietnam War is a remarkable and important part of American history, for the Vietnamese it was just another iteration of a two-millennia-long struggle for independence (a history not dissimilar from those of Iraq or Afghanistan). Vietnam was a palimpsest onto which various empires wrote their own stories, all of which the Vietnamese struggled mightily to erase. The Chinese had the longest tenure and designated Vietnam “Annam,” or “pacified south.” The official name was more revealing—“The Protectorate General to Pacify the South”; the present participle hints that even the most enduring hegemons had difficulty keeping hold of a region that wanted no foreign masters. This history did not deter the French, who arrived as China collapsed in the nineteenth century, any more than it dissuaded the Axis Japanese who booted the French. When it was Axis Japan’s turn for defeat, the Americans expressed understandable misgivings about French reoccupation of Vietnam. But the French returned, flailed against the guerrillas for a time, and then evacuated, leaving behind a nation partitioned between a communist junta in the North and an ugly military dictatorship in the South, whose only redeeming quality for the West was its notional capitalism.

In a different era, Vietnam could have been left to its own devices, but the Cold War was raging through proxy fights the Communists seemed to be winning in the Fifties. Communists had established control of Eastern Europe in 1945, China in 1949, and North Korea by 1953, and they were making advances in Latin America. South Vietnam looked vulnerable, and President Eisenhower worried that new victories would embolden other communist revolutionaries. Given events, the “domino theory” was not entirely ludicrous, nor were the atrocities of communism fictional or wholly unknown (though the young Boomers often ignored them).

However, Eisenhower had been elected to stop one proxy fight against communism and had little personal or political appetite for another war. Instead of combat troops, Eisenhower dispatched a handful of advisers and special operatives in the 1950s. His successor, John F. Kennedy, amplified these efforts, but also refused formal combat. While the United States had a meaningful presence in Vietnam, it had not committed to full war, and there were even signs (albeit highly inconclusive) that Kennedy considered abandoning Vietnam outright.

The election of 1964, however, made a wider conflict inevitable, and this poor decision can be placed almost entirely at the feet of other generations. But the wider war finally dragged Boomers into the mix, because the two contestants in 1964 agreed that a real war was in the offing. Senator Barry Goldwater, the Republican from Arizona, was pitted against JFK’s successor, Lyndon Johnson, and the two clashed dramatically over domestic policies in ways that defined the following decades; we’ll return to those issues in Chapter 6. However, both candidates agreed on a full war in Vietnam. Goldwater was an anticommunist hawk, and his motivations were straightforward. Johnson was also anticommunist, and proving it overseas was helpful to offset criticisms that his social programs at home veered uncomfortably toward socialism. Militarism was not expected to be overly costly, because while paddy-peasants might defy the pusillanimous French, they would be crushed by mighty America. The difficulty was that the war would require American bodies, and at the time, those bodies belonged to the Boomers.

Vietnam: The Unremarkable War

Nothing about the statistics suggested that Vietnam-qua-war would be the catalyst for the dramatic social struggles it ultimately provoked. Vietnam was a moderate war and somewhat collateral to core American interests. One would never know this from tapping Boomer memories, but what the numbers show is a mid-grade proxy war, and it’s helpful to review them so as not to be trapped by the idea that Vietnam was a struggle of world-historical importance to be resisted by whatever means Boomers found convenient.

In blood and money, Vietnam was modest for America. There were 58,307 dead and 303,644 wounded, death rates about half those of World War I and less than one-seventh of World War II.* American losses were much closer to those experienced in the Korean War (36,000) and lower than those borne by France during its own twentieth-century conflict in Southeast Asia (90,000 lost across the French Empire). Though roughly as deadly, neither the America-Korean nor French-Vietnamese wars sparked major domestic upheavals. Vietnam wasn’t even particularly expensive. Measured as a fraction of annual GDP, combat operations in Vietnam cost 2.3 percent at its peak, substantially less than Korea at its height, somewhat more than the War on Terror, and an order of magnitude less than World War II.5

As for Vietnam’s supposedly unique length, it was long but not always intense. For most of the period 1955–1964, personnel numbered in the hundreds and were not involved in formal combat. Many Americans were not even aware that the United States had a presence in Vietnam, nor did they care, with almost two-thirds of Americans saying as late as 1964 that they paid “little or no attention to developments in South Vietnam.”6 On the ground, only five years saw elevated troop levels and the total number of person-years was notably lower than for other major conflicts. (The recent wars in Iraq and Afghanistan on this metric have been about as long a slog.) Vietnam dragged on, but it commanded intense attention for only a few years, ones that happened to overlap with the draft of the Boomers.

As for Vietnam’s reputation as a dirty, an immoral, and, above all, an unsuccessful war, it was again, by history’s depressing standards, unremarkable. The justifications were neither new nor entirely unreasonable. The Korean War set a precedent for communist containment, and the domino theory wasn’t divorced from reality. If anything, the argument had gotten stronger since Korea, given new repressions in the Eastern Bloc. It’s true Johnson’s excuse for the war—a supposedly outrageous attack on an American ship in the Gulf of Tonkin (which led to the eponymous resolution authorizing force)—depended on flexibility with the truth. President Johnson’s mendacity about Tonkin emerged later and, regrettably, represented no departure from the sorts of embroidery used to justify America’s often-dubious foreign policy. Indeed, it was no different from the sorts of dissimulation the Boomers themselves used for their own wars, as the most recent war against Iraq showed. While Vietnam was a failure, that failure came after the domestic strife, and the loss was neither unprecedented nor a strategic catastrophe. Korea was at best a half victory, and whatever the recent operations in Iraq and Afghanistan are or might be, “unqualified success” will not be the first term reached for. The easy explanations about Vietnam as a long, dirty, expensive, unprecedented failure, cannot themselves justify Vietnam’s special place in the culture.

Dodging and Its Discontents

Failure to conform to social norms with respect to lawful behaviors… deceitfulness, as indicated by repeated lying, use of aliases or conning others for personal [gain]…

Deceit and manipulation are central features of antisocial personality disorder…

—DSM-V7

If Vietnam was a modest war, deadly and fraudulent but not especially so in its particulars, why did it prove so divisive? In a word, Boomers. As a group, the Boomers managed to be simultaneously for the war and against serving in it. Their responses to Vietnam were confused, hypocritical, exploitative, and illegal, a far cry from the unstained moral crusade produced by the laundromat of Boomer nostalgia.

Of all the war’s problems, the mechanics of the draft and its evasion proved the most divisive, and the most illuminating of the Boomers’ actual intentions—it was now that sociopathy really emerged. Whether or not they liked it (most did not), the male half of the Boomers had to engage with Vietnam upon adulthood, because Selective Service, aka the draft, required men to register at age 18, though they would not be eligible for induction until 18½, with primary eligibility lasting until age 26.8 So the trick, for those disinclined to service, was to outlast the draft window. However, while the draft supplied substantial manpower, the Vietnam force was not quite what people have (re)imagined. Only a modest fraction of forces was drafted, not all of these drafted went to Vietnam, and once in the war, the likelihood of fatality was significantly lower than it had been for prior conflicts—which is not to say that the war wasn’t terrifying, only that it wasn’t the all-consuming monster of fatal conscription of some imaginations.

Not Quite a Draft Army

What’s going on here? There is some confusion about the degree of conscription during Vietnam—the draft was more important socially than statistically—and not all military personnel served in Vietnam, and not all of those in Vietnam served in combat. The Pentagon did send a consequential number of Boomers to Vietnam against their will; just not as many as commonly imagined.9

Whatever the percentages, many simply did not want to serve and options were at hand: deferments and exemptions. At the beginning of the 1960s, students in college or technical school could avoid being drafted for as long as they remained enrolled. Others were rejected for obvious reasons like physical unfitness and moral turpitude. (From a brief time, marriage also provided a deferment.) The draft was modified in 1967, raising the maximum draft age to thirty-five and curtailing student deferments to the completion of a baccalaureate program or a student’s twenty-fourth birthday, whichever came first.10 Tellingly, the Boomers’ reactions to the Vietnam War tended to track both the intensity of the war and the mechanics of the draft itself. It’s not that creaky moral justifications for the war somehow got worse, it’s that the war, specifically the draft, got worse for the Boomers.

Today, popular memory presents Vietnam as a story of a war opposed by the young, but that is convenient rebranding. Young people today tend toward the pacific. During the 1960s youthful Americans (i.e., Boomers) were the most militant cohort. Contemporary surveys routinely showed younger groups (generally under thirty) as the most supportive of the Vietnam War and of aggressive strategies for prosecuting it. These prowar attitudes proved stubborn, so despite accumulating news reports of reversals and abuses from 1966 onward, young people remained throughout the war the group least likely to view the engagement as an error.

Vietnam—The Changing Face of Deferrals

What’s going on here? As the Vietnam war intensified, some deferrals became harder to get, and this contributed to the rising angst of the late 1960s. As college deferrals became less routine and the chances of mainstream Boomers serving in Vietnam increased, protests became more intense even though the morality of the war remained fairly constant. Note also that the number of conscientious objectors was never material.11

From 1965 to 1971, the war’s peak years, pollers at Gallup asked Americans the same question: “In view of the developments since we entered the fighting in Vietnam, do you think the US made a mistake in sending troops to fight in Vietnam?”12 It wasn’t until the second half of 1968 (we’ll see why) that a majority of young Americans came to view Vietnam as a mistake and, mistake or not, youth had been stronger supporters of escalation than their elders.13 Older Americans favored less aggressive strategies, up to and including abandonment of the Vietnam project. As late as 1965–1966, younger groups were more hawkish, and college-educated young men aged eighteen to twenty-four “tend[ed] to support the President’s Vietnam policies more strongly than any other demographic group in the population” (the president’s policies, at that time, being escalation).14 Even by the war’s end, when majorities in all groups harbored reservations, many young people remained aggressive, though the tenor of their opinions did evolve dramatically from mid-1968 to 1969.15 Decades later, almost 70 percent of Americans view Vietnam as a mistake, but what matters for us is what people thought at the time, without the benefit of hindsight.16 Therefore, the reality was the inverse of the fable, a youth hungrier for war than many older Americans. By no means were most draft dodgers hypocrites judged on their war attitudes, since many did oppose the war. But many were—and almost all dodging, regardless of ideological consistency, had sociopathic overtones, as we will see.

The other revealing surprise is the support the war enjoyed, during its inception, among the educated. A glance at the photographic record of the antiwar movement shows a sea of white college students, so it’s easy to get the impression that the educated elite was against the war en masse, especially because more educated groups today trend against military interventions. But until early 1968, better educated groups skewed in favor of the war, while less educated and less affluent groups skewed against the war, not least because the disadvantaged had the highest chance of being drafted.17 The reason there are so many old photos of college protestors is because deferments allowed so many Boomers to be in college to protest rather than in Vietnam to fight (or, in some cases, to simply and quietly pursue their studies). Only around 1968 did educational opinion gaps wither, not coincidentally as college deferments became somewhat harder to obtain.

Accounting for these demographic surprises, the unexpected belligerence of the young and the educated, and their crucial transformations from 1967 to 1969, are two factors: the progress of the war and the mechanics of the draft. In a significant sense, the war really began not in the 1950s, when the first small groups of advisers arrived in Vietnam, but in March 1965, when the first combat troops arrived to fight the ground war. At the beginning, the war was expected to be easy. General William Westmoreland’s three-point plan for victory scheduled triumph within two years of initial deployments.*,18 For a time, the American people patiently awaited success, but even as troop levels rose again and again, Westmoreland’s easy win slipped further away.

The turning point came in early 1968. Westmoreland once again predicted imminent victory, but even as he was doing so the Vietcong (South Vietnamese communist insurgents) and the North Vietnamese were preparing a major offensive to coincide with Tet, the Vietnamese New Year. The Tet Offensive shocked the American public, not because it succeeded in the field—it did not—but because the enemy was supposed to have been so depleted as to make anything like Tet impossible. Clearly, there was some divergence between the American command’s sunny reports and the reality on the ground. American public opinion quickly reversed from strong net support of the war to an even split. It would deteriorate from there, and mainstream media, including Newsweek, the Wall Street Journal, and critically, influential CBS anchorman Walter Cronkite, began to worry publicly that the war was unwinnable. However, even after the Tet Offensive, a majority of young people still did not view the war as a mistake and continued to favor belligerent policies.

What would cause young people, potential draftees, to support a war in which they presumably had the most, personally, to lose? One compelling explanation is that the young and better educated, who were most in favor of the war, had no realistic expectation that they would be forced to serve. This freed them to support a war most Boomers expected to be of limited personal consequence. First, only a fraction of forces were drafted; the substantial majority volunteered, though the draft did persuade some to sign up voluntarily if only to select the service they preferred, and the total number of volunteers was far smaller than the total number of deferments.19 For many, educational deferments provided a sense of safety. Deferments, created in 1951, favored college students and those who scored well on aptitude tests, as well as those for whom war would be a “hardship” due to family or other circumstances. Until the draft picked up in 1965, deferments effectively operated as permanent exemptions from service.20 Deferments were not some odd loophole, they were explicit social engineering designed to “channel” brighter students into useful occupations.21 Over fifteen million Boomers in a position to do so eagerly collaborated, using various deferment options.*,22

As the war intensified, so did the draft, and use and exploitation of the deferment system, and controversy over the war. By early 1966, two million men had secured college deferments. The number of students taking the (biased) Selective Service Qualification Test, success on which could either confirm or imperil deferment, rose from 2,145 in 1963 to 767,935 in 1966.*,23 Obviously, many students wanted to go to college whatever the situation overseas. However, a great many others simply wished to avoid Vietnam. This becomes evident when looking at the rates of college enrollment before and after the draft—enrollments spiked during the draft’s height and tailed off as the draft and war wound down, especially for higher-status white men with bad draft numbers.24 Even enrollment in seminaries, another source of deferral, followed the same pattern.25 Enrollments went beyond coincidence. Statistical analysis shows that avoiding the draft was a significant causal factor in the migration of young people into education during the peak draft years.26

All else being roughly equal, the inescapable (statistically corroborated) conclusion is that many Boomers gamed the system to get out of the war, and they had plenty of guidance from a whole cottage industry churning out items like the popular Handbook for Conscientious Objectors, which went through multiple editions. Also on hand was none other than Dr. Spock, the author of the guide that had done so much to influence Boomer child rearing, who counseled his generational charges to resist the draft in the hope that “100,000, 200,000 or even 500,000 young Americans [would] either refuse to be drafted or to obey orders if in military services.” Spock also encouraged resistance through refusal to pay taxes, which became a Boomer theme in other ways and contexts.27

Playing the system became an art, effected by means whose baroque complexity makes clear the intent of its practitioners. The form was perfected by one William Jefferson Clinton, who established an early pattern of hypertechnical compliance and regulatory manipulation, garnished as necessary by occasional dishonesty. Like millions of Boomers, Clinton received a deferment during college and secured an additional deferment for graduate school, as was customary and legal. However, after graduate school deferments were eliminated in 1968, Clinton became eligible and received an induction notice in 1969. Facing this inconvenience, Clinton signed an agreement with the Reserve Officer Training Corp (ROTC), which lowered his chances of being immediately inducted, though it did require him to commit to a period of military service at a later date (perhaps after the war had ended, as it shortly would). The rules changed again when Nixon allowed graduate students to postpone induction until their current school year was complete. Clinton took advantage of this development, breaking his agreement with ROTC (which had a 100 percent chance of requiring service) presumably in the hope—ultimately successful—that a draft lottery would be introduced, which would by definition have better odds than ROTC’s sure thing. As usual, Clinton’s timing was apt: It was well understood that a draft lottery was coming, and even if Clinton drew a low number (which meant a high chance of being drafted), Nixon had been elected the prior year to bring an end to the war, which might moot the entire question. The essential thing was to continue dragging out the process, just as the Boomers are now doing with Social Security and other programs.* In the end, Clinton’s gamble succeeded; he got a good draft number, and troop levels peaked in 1969, reducing draft pressures thereafter. The net effect of Clinton’s several years of maneuvering meant that he was able to sit out the war.28 (Co-Boomer Dick Cheney, meanwhile, racked up five deferments of his own—and while the number is startling, his deferments were more straightforward.29)

The lottery worked for Clinton, but its introduction was not met with enthusiasm by younger students. When Clinton played the lottery, he was well out of college and had exhausted all other options (other, that is, than serving); the lottery had become his best option for avoiding the war. For students still of college age and able to attend, the innovation of the lottery was much worse than the status quo of guaranteed deferral. A 1966 survey conducted at Harvard by the Undergraduate Council showed 70 percent of students in favor of retaining the existing system of college deferments over a “more equitable” lottery system.30 Charitably interpreted, this meant students believed that maintaining uninterrupted study was a better means of social organization than spreading the burden of the war. More realistically, it meant that they wanted to save themselves even if it meant perpetuating an unfair system that exploited groups in the worst position to defend themselves.

And the deferment system was exploitative. Whether one was for or against the war, whether deferment was or was not ideologically consistent, deferment by middle-class Boomers simply shifted costs to less-advantaged groups. The military requisitioned a fixed number of people every year, so each student protected by a college deferment had to be replaced by someone else—and that someone tended to be poorer and less educated. The ranks reflected this. One rough estimate of enlisted demographics put composition at “about 25 percent poor, 55 percent working class, and 20 percent middle class, with a statistically negligible number of wealthy” and other analyses showed that the likelihood of service, especially combat service, was substantially lower for middle-and high-income groups.31 In other words, the bottom third or so provided about four-fifths of the manpower. Senator John McCain, who otherwise holds a fairly untroubled view of Vietnam, thought this was the war’s true injustice: “Those who were better off economically did not carry out their obligations, so we forced the Hispanic, the ghetto black, and the Appalachian white to fight and die. That to me was the greatest crime and injustice of the Vietnam War.”32 When a revanchist Republican, one who adorned his hawkish presidential campaign with a wingnut governor of a distant province, provides voice for the “ghetto black,” you know something morally troubling went down.

With deferments, it could not have been otherwise. Even though college was cheaper in the 1960s, it was not entirely free, and it required students to forgo years of full income while they studied. Students who deferred had at least some means, and richer students were better prepared for college in the first place. Therefore, the deferment system almost automatically favored people higher on the socioeconomic ladder (three of whom would be president). At least among the Boom’s more middle-class members, the first signs of sociopathy begin to appear—self-service at the cost of others (the poor, minorities), a casual attitude toward the law (e.g., Clinton’s representative manipulations), and actions contrary to social norms (e.g., failure to heed the nation’s call, breaking the law). The deep compromises entailed in avoiding the war help explain the general fury over draft dodging that persists. Oddly, few care if a politician volunteered for, or otherwise supported, a war that everyone now hates—it’s the dodging that rankles. People rightly sense something unsavory occurred.

Although college deferments were legal—channeling better/advantaged students into school being an explicit government aim—the Boomers abused the system generally. Some students faked an interest in college, wasting resources better spent on those who actually wanted the education. Others manufactured evidence to secure other sorts of deferments when college couldn’t supply the necessary shelter. Those with access to sympathetic physicians, psychologists, and other professionals (i.e., monied Boomers) could and did present themselves as unfit for service, even when they were not. Enterprising candidates could also produce unfitness in themselves—James Fallows, who achieved fame as a journalist in later years, reportedly starved himself down to a disqualifying 120 pounds. He eventually confessed to lingering guilt for avoiding the draft while the less informed were mustered in.33

The most infamous tactic was outright dodging, which involved leaving the country. Dodging wasn’t the act of penniless rebels, because it often required a passport (which only wealthier Americans tended to have), funds for passage, and money to live in countries that disbarred from gainful employment Boomers on the lam. Outright dodging was both completely illegal and morally problematic. It was also expensive and inconvenient, and so the numbers availing themselves of a refreshing, well-timed jaunt to Stockholm were never particularly large.

There was an honorable way to avoid the war, and that was conscientious objection, a forthright refusal to serve on moral or religious grounds, undertaken legally through the Selective Service system. Even this noble solution was not without its inequities, as securing status as a conscientious objector (or “CO”) required both knowledge of the CO exemption and the rhetorical skills necessary to persuade a draft board that one’s objections were sincere and divorced from mere personal self-interest, a strategy all but tailored for use by elites and not the general population. Still, for those with sincere antiwar convictions, CO would seem the most obvious and appealing route to depriving the war of bodies.* For sociopaths, however, CO was among the least desirable options, because it required sincerity, effort to secure the deferment, and some form of alternative service, usually low-paid and incommodious. It is no surprise, then, that CO was never widely used; far fewer applied for CO than for college deferment. About 175,000 were accepted (the Selective Service was not overly forthcoming about CO applications, but there were probably a few hundred thousand during the entire war, and those already in the military had their applications granted frequently—about 63 to 77 percent were approved in the war’s last years).34

All conventional draft avoidance tactics required money and a certain knowledge and savviness about the system simply not available to less advantaged groups. The net effect was that college deferments became an exercise of class privilege, and, given the overrepresentation of minorities among the poor, of racial discrimination. It was not unlike the hiring of substitutes during the Civil War, during which a draftee could simply pay another person to take his place, but with the government itself managing the transaction in the case of the Vietnam draft. At least during the Civil War the substitute got a cash bounty from his sponsoring civilian—it was, in a sense, a cleaner transaction.

As usual, the options for those lower on the ladder were worse and if the dilemmas of the disadvantaged demand sympathy, some of their solutions do not. For those without college deferments or the means and education to exploit alternatives like CO, only two strategies remained. If called, the first option was to serve, which most did. The second was to take advantage of a “moral disqualification,” a status routinely provided to those in prison, on parole, or awaiting trial. Indeed, even if a person were presently free, a criminal record of any kind was perceived to exempt its holder from service. So while many privileged students went to college, some of their poorer counterparts turned to crime. Several studies confirm the relationship between a rise in crime in the 1960s and the draft, with avoidance as a causal explanation.35 This was particularly the case for blacks and people of lower socioeconomic status, but not the case for wealthier whites (probably not because they were inherently more law-abiding, just that they had better options).36 While a lack of options mitigates the offense, the simple fact is that using crime to avoid the draft is, obviously, criminal; indeed, doubly so. (One paper pertinently describes dodging down as “antisocial.”37) Worse, crimes had to be reasonably significant to really carry weight with draft boards, and that meant inflicting some sort of harm on innocent victims, another instance of sociopathy. The perpetrators bore their own costs, as criminal records permanently reduce economic and social prospects, helping perpetuate an urban underclass.

Aside from creating lawlessness at home, draft avoidance caused serious problems in the military. Many less-privileged recruits were not qualified to serve, having failed either the physical or mental aptitude tests, usually the latter. As it became harder to satisfy recruiting demands because of the large number of students protected by deferment, the military simply admitted unqualified candidates, who predictably did not thrive in Vietnam. The four hundred thousand troops admitted under relaxed standards suffered twice the average death rate. There is, therefore, a causal connection between excess battlefield deaths and the abuse of the deferment system, although one intermediated by an implacable Defense Department.

These substandard troops also tended to be—not for reasons of inherent aptitude, but as a function in inequitable education stateside—disproportionately black. After the military waived its standards, the first major pool of substandard recruits was 41 percent black.38 This was just another permutation of the racial skew in the military, where minorities suffered disproportionate risks. At 12–13 percent, the black fraction of the total military was roughly in line with the population, but blacks represented about a quarter of the fighting army in Vietnam and sometimes more, compensating for a white recruitment pool drained away into deferments, the officer and administrative elites, National Guard assignments (the strategy of George W. Bush), and other combat-avoiding strategies.39

Drunk and Disorderly: Boomers in Uniform

Individuals with antisocial personality disorder… may
[have] a pattern of repeated absences from work…

These individuals may receive dishonorable
discharges from the armed services…

They may have associated… substance abuse disorders…

They may repeatedly perform acts that are grounds
for arrest… such as destroying property…

These individuals also display a reckless disregard
for the safety of themselves or others.

—DSM-V40

Once shoved into uniform, Boomer behavior deteriorated further. The force deployed in Vietnam was perhaps the worst fielded in the modern era, plagued by indiscipline, drug abuse, insubordination, desertion, and war crimes, with occasional helpings of outright treason and murder. Draft armies tend to be less orderly than volunteer forces, but the Boomer-heavy force operating in Vietnam was vastly worse than the draft armies that fought in Korea or the World Wars, in predictably sociopathic ways. And given how widespread misconduct was—the percentage using drugs was almost certainly higher than the percentage of those drafted, for example—misconduct afflicted both draftees and volunteers.

Problems in Vietnam became so severe that Colonel Robert Heinl, a seasoned marine, lamented them in a 1971 article for the Armed Forces Journal, and his conclusions have been generally confirmed by other scholarly work.41 Heinl described an army whose ordering principle, that of command, was vanishing. In Vietnam, soldiers routinely refused orders, often dramatically, as when the 196th Light Infantry Brigade “publicly sat down on the battlefield” like a group of dyspeptic school children.42 To avoid the risks of combat, other units engaged in “search and evade” (instead of “search and destroy”) missions. The Vietcong ordered its own units not to engage Americans who did not engage them, happy to exploit enemy indiscipline. Search and evade might have worked for the units doing the evading, but not for anyone else. When the enemy couldn’t be avoided, another “combat refusal” entailed deliberately missing when firing at the enemy. In this case, however, the enemy was free to fire back unless it somehow divined its opponents’ pacific intentions through the jungle chaos; of course, fuzzy symbolism and wishful thinking always trumped reason in the Boomer calculus. For rational people, it’s hard to see how these “combat refusals” did anything but increase the risks for other soldiers.

If insubordination failed to communicate the displeasure of the rank-and-file with its orders, there was always the simple expedient of killing those doing the ordering. These murders were called “fraggings,” after the fragmentation grenades whose explosions made them difficult to trace, and thus the assassin’s choice. The Department of Defense recorded 96 fraggings in 1969 and 209 in 1970; in total, Vietnam witnessed at least 551 fragging incidents causing 86 deaths and over 700 injuries.43 There are no tallies for the number of officers assassinated by other means more widely available, like guns and knives, which doubtless added to the total. A few troops even put bounties on unpopular commanders, at least one of which was advertised in an underground GI newspaper. Nothing like this had happened before and nothing like it has happened since. During the lengthy recent operations in Iraq and Afghanistan, which feature no Boomer combat troops, there have been almost no fraggings or other attempted assassinations.

The litany of indiscipline continued. Sabotage became a problem, ranging from the dynamiting of a telephone facility to, in the Navy’s case alone, “almost 500 cases of arson, sabotage, or wrongful destruction on its ships.”44Drug use infiltrated military culture. While estimates vary, heroin affected many troops (from 4 percent to 22 percent) and use of marijuana may have exceeded 50 percent (both having significantly increased from 1967 to 1970), drinking was heavy, and soldiers routinely turned up for duty armed and intoxicated.45 Drug discharges ramped up throughout the war until the military more or less gave up on the problem and the war. Winston Churchill used to complain that the British navy was all rum, sodomy, and the lash; the Boomer army was rum and hash, and as for sodomy, and what happened in the underage and notoriously slave-like bordellos on shore leave, is best left unimagined.

Desertions also ran rampant, with more than 507,000 instances between 1964 and 1973, committed by about 440,000 individuals.46 Because the definition of “desertion” tightened up during the Korean War, it is hard to directly compare the experiences of the Vietnam War with earlier conflicts using drafted soldiers. But reasonable estimates place Vietnam desertion rates at more than twice those of Korea and higher than in World War II (with the exception a few months in 1945). Total desertions topped Korea, and even World War II, which involved vastly larger armies. Even in Vietnam, desertion had not been a problem as late as 1966, before Boomer draftees arrived in quantity. In the Army, the desertion rate more than tripled, from 14.7 per thousand in 1966 to 52.3 per thousand, in 1970.47 This period coincided with the declining availability of deferments, leaving legions of entitled and resentful students stuck in the jungle. Desertion rates in Vietnam remain the highest and most sustained experienced by American forces anytime since the Civil War.

In this catalogue of dysfunction, some of the worst examples (besides the murder of American officers by their subordinates) were the crimes perpetrated against the Vietnamese. The most significant of these were the bombings of civilians orchestrated from Washington and the illegal campaigns waged in Laos and Cambodia, which collectively accounted for most unnecessary deaths. Other generations bear responsibility for those disasters. The Boomers get the blame for local, freelance disasters. Soldiers sometimes ran wild, committing atrocities in the paddies and villages, including the infamous incident at My Lai. Unfortunately, in this one respect, the Vietnam War was undistinguished from earlier conflicts, which featured their own crimes. Fortunately, the last war to feature Boomer troops was also the last to feature widespread and deadly abuses committed at the troops’ own initiative. Recent wars have featured occasional outrages like Abu Ghraib, but nothing at the scale of My Lai or, at least, nothing not ordered by senior officials (many of them Boomers).

The Legacy: All Harm, No Foul

They generally fail to compensate or make amends for their behavior.

—DSM-V

The scope of misconduct during Vietnam rules out the few-bad-apple theories; the conduct was systemic, and given the nature of the draft and the composition of those involved, it was also generational. However, it’s important to note that the consequences were social, not strategic. The war was a lost cause from the beginning, as Ho Chi Minh made clear to the French in 1946, saying to them that “you can kill ten of my men for every one I kill of yours… but even at those odds you will lose and I will win.”48 As the French were dispatched, so were the Americans; there were too many Vietnamese guerrillas and not enough reasons to be in Vietnam. America’s setback was not the Boomers’ fault—and as we will see, neither was the peace the Boomers’ victory, since their protests shriveled along with the danger of being drafted.

What is hard to doubt is that many of the strategies for avoiding the draft and the indiscipline of troops once in Vietnam made a bad war that much worse. Older civilian and military commanders bear enormous blame for presiding over a bad war and running a discriminatory draft; the Boomers must shoulder responsibility for reacting badly to an admittedly bad situation. Deferments could be legally exploited, but the fact that a system permits exploitation does not mean a person must engage in it. No one forced Boomers to opt for a deferment over CO status, any more than corporations today are forced into tax inversions to avoid paying their fair share; both are legal, neither is uncompromised. Worse still, of course, was manufacturing medical exemptions, which was fraud, and securing moral disqualification by victimizing others, which was crime. Indiscipline made the war more lethal for everyone, and fraggings were outright treason.

The various strategies of subversion are often sanitized as a noble moral protest, but it has been the case since Socrates (one of the distasteful white males then being excised from the canon) that citizens do not have the right to ignore laws because they disagree with a policy.49 Lawlessness is lawlessness, and inherently antisocial; it can be justified only in extreme cases where no reasonable alternatives exist. (CO was one such alternative.) Anything else is society à la carte—anarchy, really.

Protests were one thing; such speech is a right and often a responsibility. Draft avoidance and insubordination were something else. Were they at least effective? That hippies must be forced to reach toward their Machiavelli says a lot itself, but did the ends at least justify the means? Not really, if for no other reason than that they were too little, too late. Ho’s meat-grinder tactics rendered irrelevant all other details. All that mattered was when the American people got Ho’s message, which they did. As a practical matter, the election of 1968 committed the United States to an exit and the war duly peaked in early 1969, before the most intense dodging and military dysfunction.

As for crafting some redeeming moral narrative around draft avoidance, doing so would require locating motives where subverting the war effort was at least as important as saving the dodger’s own skin. It would have been hard for serious people to believe that dodging was an effective means of subversion, because at no point did dodging deprive the war of bodies generally, just of specific bodies, to be replaced by poorer, less qualified substitutes. And the most intense period of draft avoidance occurred after the United States began withdrawal, blunting its already small effect.

Vietnam histories tend to end around January 1973, when the Paris Peace Accords were signed, which is a mistake, because what came next sheds extra light on what really happened before. After ’73, America cut and ran, leaving behind chaos that no major domestic group demanded the nation address. The first victims of America’s collective hand washing were, of course, the South Vietnamese. No one seriously expected South Vietnam—an ally, remember—to survive on its own, and on April 30, 1975, Saigon fell. Though Vietnam was now geographically whole, it had been devastated by war, with several million dead and wounded, the countryside ravaged by American bombs and defoliants, and the economy in shambles—and the North eager to settle scores with America’s collaborators in the South.

What about the protest movement, which had previously effected such sympathy for the Vietnamese? After all, protestors at the 1968 Democratic National Convention had waved North Vietnamese flags in support of socialist comrades, with some protestors offering to take up communist arms (unlikely), and alternative newspapers seethed against the injustices being done to Vietnam. By the end, there was no doubt America had helped to create a tremendous mess, so given all the moral outrage and the expressions of solidarity, a sustained movement for reconciliation and rebuilding would have been only natural. It never really came, nor did the once-activist Boomers dust off their protest gear and agitate for such. The closest thing Vietnam got to conciliation came from the Nixon White House, not the Haight-Ashbury, and those negotiations stalled before being rendered moot by the war between Vietnam and Cambodia.

The point is not to blame the Boomers for the failure to make amends—older generations bear responsibility—but to use Boomer passivity after the war to illuminate the generation’s true motivations during the protest era.* As the threat of the draft abated, so did the Boomers’ furious energy. It wasn’t that the injustice in Vietnam had ended, it was that the peril visited on the Boomers had. Perhaps it had been about saving one’s skin all along.

Later, Americans, including the Boomers, resented even the smallest tokens of repentance. When the government eventually accepted about half a million Vietnamese refugees fleeing reprisals, it did so over public objection. A 1975 Gallup poll found 52 percent of Americans against Vietnamese immigration with only 36 percent in favor; roughly the same held true in 1979.50 Jerry Brown, the governor of California and icon of the youthful Left, protested attempts at resettlement and demanded that any bill allowing it give priority to Americans seeking jobs (as, apparently, did Joe Biden). The biggest group of those seeking jobs in the 1970s were, of course, the Boomers. Boomer first, of course, has also been a hallmark of the wars run by the Boomers themselves, where they cannot even be bothered to spend a tiny amount of political capital to retrieve military allies like translators from probable assassination in Iraq and Afghanistan.51

Vietnam had one final lesson for the Boomers: They could get away with their misdeeds. Prosecutors had brought some high-profile cases against draft dodgers during the war, though few were convicted and sentenced. But even the hint of disapprobation was unacceptable to Boomers accustomed to unqualified praise. Almost immediately after the war ended, and with Boomer voting power on the rise, dodgers were duly forgiven. President Gerald Ford wanted forgiveness to be conditioned on community service, which was too much to ask.52 Carter one-upped Ford during the 1977 campaign, proposing comprehensive amnesty to all civilians who had violated the draft rules (i.e., those who had dodged successfully)—a direct sop to the Boomers. In 1977, Carter fulfilled his campaign promise by issuing Executive Order 11967 granting (with very limited exceptions) a general pardon. This was a dramatic instance of the rising political power of the Boomers and a certain sociopathy—it was a pardon tailor-made for them, and of course, a pardon implies a crime. Despite the other challenges of the 1970s, Carter found the issue (and its constituency) sufficiently important that he made the pardon his first official act.

CHAPTER FOUR

EMPIRE OF SELF

Individuals with antisocial personality disorder and histrionic
personality disorder share a tendency to be impulsive,
superficial, excitement seeking, reckless, seductive.…

—DSM-V1

If you can remember anything about the
Sixties, you weren’t really there.

—attributed variously

Despite rising prosperity and expanding civil rights, the Boomers found much to dislike about the America they inherited, from Vietnam to the restrictive set of cultural and social assumptions held by earlier generations. They duly attacked, using as their weapon the aptly named counterculture, which was above all a doctrine of opposition. The Leftist version is well known: antiwar, antistate, anticonformity. Rather surprisingly, the Right had its own version, a rebellion against a big government and a regulatory/welfare orthodoxy that many midcentury Republicans had helped build. The Right’s counterculture gets forgotten, paradoxically because it achieved greater success becoming not so much a counterculture as the culture, and perhaps also because of its shared and inconvenient origins with the Leftist version. But before the revolution would be political, it had to be personal, fashioning a template of sociopathic improvidence that would provide the policy agenda once Boomers gained control of the state. The first agenda item would be unfettering individuals from the bonds of society, allowing the Boomers’ true priorities, license and indulgence, to flourish.

The Hedonist at Home: Sex and Drugs

[Sociopaths] may have a history of many sexual partners…

They may have associated disorders… substance use
disorders… and other disorders of impulse control…

[They] also often have personality features that meet criteria
for other personality disorders, particularly borderline,
histrionic, and narcissistic personality disorders.

—DSM-V2

As we’ve seen, the Boomers’ engagement with Vietnam faded along with the draft. The Boomers’ growing emphasis on personal satisfaction proved more enduring. As a historical moment, then, 1967 is best understood not as a summer of love or a season of protest, but as Year One of the Self.

The defining trait of all previous societies had been that they were social—a body of people more or less united by common goals and values. The individual was subordinated to the group or, as the other great midcentury Spock put it, “the needs of the many outweighed the needs of the few, or the one.” A social imperative doesn’t require socialism itself, whose practical instantiations anyway tend less toward collectivist paradise than military oligarchy. It does, however, require a broader view, in which individual liberties balance against general welfare. Unfortunately, sociopaths are antisocial by nature, and their lack of empathy and foresight consigns them to view society only as a restraint on individual freedom of action or a conduit for unearned treats, rather than a font of general betterment.

It’s sometimes difficult to see the individualist current of the Sixties and Seventies because so much of the Leftist counterculture notionally embraced socialist goals, with hippie communes founded on conceptions of joint property almost tailor-made to offend the establishment’s vigorous anticommunism. Offense was certainly a substantial part of the point and if Épater le bourgeois! was the rallying cry, then on only those grounds did communal experiments succeed. In every other way, tie-dyed, Marxist-Leninist havens were inherently dysfunctional and failed to provide the material comforts the Boomers found to be their true, long-term priority. The socialist experiment withered away. The exercises in individual license did not.

At heart, it was always and really about that license, whatever the official branding. Formally, the Love Pageant Rally of 1966 and subsequent “Human Be-In” had political goals, trying to unite in pursuit of a new age both the antiwar movement (whose elites viewed the hippies as too stoned) and the hippies (who considered the antiwar movement as too uptight and enmeshed in conventional politics). In practice, the culmination of this effort, 1967’s Summer of Love, ended up less a synthesis of the various strands of Leftist political culture than a straight-up antithesis, standing against middle-class morality on matters of drugs and sex and for very little else.*

In keeping with the hedonic theme, many ostensibly political events were really more about drugs than demos. The Pageant’s date, October 6, 1966, was not the anniversary of the Gulf of Tonkin Incident, the Emancipation Proclamation, women’s suffrage, or anything too goody-goody or consistent with political platform. Rather, 10/6/66 was the day when LSD became illegal in California, an event to be protested, inevitably, by taking LSD.3 The government somehow failed to wither in response, any more than the Pentagon levitated in response to hippie chanting a year later, though Department of Defense graciously provided the long-haired chanters with a permit to lift the building a few feet off the ground.4

All of it was sophomoric and ludicrous, and if it had been conceded as the (illegal) party it was that would have been one thing. Instead, many Boomers dressed up indulgence as a moral crusade, just as they had with draft dodging and would again with tax cuts and their own military adventures. (Boomers may have even believed these narratives of worthiness, a duality permitted by their training in televisual irony and suspension of disbelief.) Therefore, in the words of Sixties radical Todd Gitlin, LSD peddlers like Owsley Stanley, who “fabricated potent and pure LSD tablets in the hundreds of thousands,” were, to be clear, “not just in it for the money; they kept their prices down [and] gave out plenty of free samples” in the “service of a new age”—an entirely different matter.5 The claim was that acid and pot provided a gateway to enlightenment, intoxicating in ways more pacific and consciousness expanding than the martinis of suburban geezers (or than the street drugs that came later, which the Boomers as politically enfranchised adults violently suppressed). “It becomes necessary for us to go out of our minds in order to use our heads,” per Tim Leary, the ex-Harvard lecturer and most famous advocate of LSD.6 Leary and his followers were halfway there.*,7

All generations have had their affairs with substances, but few were as transgressive or widespread as the Boomers’. At the beginning of the Sixties, before the great mass of Boomers had come of drug-taking age, rates of marijuana experimentation among young people ran under 5 percent.8 By the early Seventies, when Boomers accounted for the entirety of the teenage population, the figure was substantially larger, approaching half, and LSD and harder drugs, previously fringe substances, had become more widespread.9

Comparing different generations at the same point in their respective life cycles, the young Boomers had notably higher rates of drinking and illegal drug use than preceding and succeeding generations—teenagers were then (as now) the heaviest users, and use rose dramatically during the 1960s and 1970s, peaked in high school seniors of 1979–1980 (i.e., coincided with the Boomers) and fell substantially thereafter.10 The use of alcohol, amphetamines, and cocaine by high schoolers and college-age populations began to fall substantially in the early 1980s, as Boomers aged out of these groups.*,11 As seniors, Boomers have pushed the rate of elder drug use substantially higher; as the government put it in 2015, “drug use is increasing among people in their fifties and early sixties. This increase is, in part, due to the aging of the baby boomers, whose rates of illicit drug use have historically been higher than previous generations.”12

There are endless Jesuitical discussions to be had about the potency of Purple Haze in the Sixties versus Hindu Kush in the Nineties, or whether LSD then was more mind-expanding than Ecstasy is now, or if today’s ADHD medication is really just yesterday’s speed. To indulge in these debates is in some sense to concede the point; the Boomers did a lot of experimenting. When compiling this part of the sociopathic inventory, there’s no need to get bogged down in too much detail. It’s sufficient that taking drugs was dramatically against social norms—even more so forty-odd years ago than now—and required breaking laws in service of personal gratification. It was, in other words, an endeavor with sociopathic overtones, and not coincidentally, the clinical guides note that drug abuse is frequently coincident with antisocial personality disorder.

As they were with substances, the Boomers were keen experimenters on matters of sex. Given the mores of the day, this too required substantial transgression—that the terms “sexual liberation” and “sexual revolution” were essentially invented in the Sixties says a lot. The revolution was against the traditional order, one hostile to carnality outside the bounds of heterosexual marriage and, even within those unions, in favor of less adventure rather than more.

Pre-Boomer America had never been entirely a temple of chastity; nineteenth-century Oneida, New York, had a community then known for its free love, though it is famous today as the source of Oneida silverware (a thought to contemplate when next at the dinner table). Even conventional communities occasionally departed from the puritan idea, as Alfred Kinsey, William Johnson, and Virginia Masters showed from the 1940s on. However, that Masters and Johnson had to rely on prostitutes for some of their initial research (good Americans being too upstanding for sex studies), and that certain discoveries, like the fact that women can have multiple orgasms, came as a surprise (to men), suggest that American sexuality was not terribly advanced.

Prudishness fell away during the Boomers’ adolescences. This was evident in the bookstands, which featured best sellers like Everything You Always Wanted to Know About Sex* (*But Were Afraid to Ask) (1969) and The Joy of Sex (1972) and in other media. Conventionally, Hollywood and mass media get much blame for driving a culture of sexuality, but it is at least as much the case that more sexuality in real life drove a more sexualized media. By the Sixties, it was ridiculous to pretend, as decency regulations like the Hays Code had, that a teenage population that was having more and more real-life sex would have their worlds shattered by filmic genitalia, and these limits crumbled. The Pawnbroker, set in the Holocaust and released in the United States in 1965, served as the unlikely vehicle for the first Code-sanctioned display of celluloid breasts, and from there matters accelerated, with the Code abolished in 1968, opening the way for semi-erotica like I Am Curious (Yellow) (released in the US in 1969), Last Tango In Paris (1972), and so on. Given what was happening in the drive-ins and theatre seats, all this was less avant la lettre than après.

However joyfully the media embraced sexuality, society remained deeply conflicted, simultaneously disapproving of casual sex while having more of it. Until about 2010, most Americans had deep reservations about premarital sex; majorities did not agree with the statement that premarital sex was “not wrong at all.”13 Nevertheless, Americans had sex earlier and earlier, even as the age of first marriage rose, suggesting that a lot of sex was premarital, if conflicted. Noticeable declines in the age at which Americans lost their virginity began with the cohorts born in the later 1940s and continued through those born in the early 1970s, almost precisely tracking the Baby Boom.14 Generations born after 1975 were a bit more conservative, with their ages at first sex rising generally.15

The Boomers were also relatively promiscuous, and what is remarkable is that this is true not only in relation to earlier generations but to those born long after the sexual revolution had taken hold. In normative terms, modest promiscuity today doesn’t bother most Americans now, but the Boomers’ practices, evaluated in their particulars and against the prevailing social context, point to sociopathic transgression.

Promiscuity was frowned on in the midcentury, and American practices generally conformed to that view. Americans born at the beginning of the twentieth century reported one sexual partner on average (presumably, the respondent’s spouse), rising to 11.68 on average for those born in the 1950s (a group composed entirely of Boomers).16 Despite loosening mores, numbers have fallen back somewhat for those born after 1970, though it remains to be seen how online and mobile app dating sites like Tinder and Scruff ultimately influence the figures.*,17 Confirming this, a study that controlled for other variables (including age) concluded that “the overwhelming majority of variation in number of sexual partners was generational”; in other words, a person’s generation mattered more than any other factor, and Boomers led the way and in some ways remain unique.18

They may engage in sexual behavior… that has
a high risk for harmful consequences.

—DSM-V19

Even though there was more sex, it was not necessarily safer sex, though Boomers had the means. The Supreme Court made prophylaxis nationally available in time to benefit most of the Boomers, and it had been widely available in many states even before the Court nationalized protection.20 Surprisingly, even as condoms, the pill, and other prophylaxis became more accessible, levels of unwanted pregnancies increased both per capita and in total. The number of teenagers seeking abortions, for instance, increased dramatically from 1973 until the mid-1980s, a period that overlapped heavily with Boomer fertility.21 (Just to be clear: abortion is being used as a proxy for responsible sex, not for general morality.) Abortion rates for all women rose from the 1955 birth cohort (the earliest data available), peaked for the 1970 cohort (just past the Boomers), and have fallen since.22

It would be tidy to attribute these trends to changes in abortion regulation, but it’s hard to pin everything on Roe v. Wade, decided in 1973. Unlike divorce, where it may take years to separate all the unhappy couples, there can only be so much backlog in the case of abortion—nine months at the outside, and, given Roe’s trimester framework, closer to three. Any spike due just to legal change therefore should have ended shortly after Roe was decided, but higher abortion rates persisted throughout the Boomers’ fertile years. Rates fell thereafter, and not because abortions became illegal or vastly harder to get—to the extent that happened, it happened after a 1992 Court decision revised Roe to forbid “undue burdens” on abortion, which Boomer legislators took as an invitation to figure out just how much due burden they could impose.23

Shifts in abortion practices were predicted by changes in rates of teenage pregnancy, where the Boomers were again anomalous. Teenage pregnancy rates rose rapidly through the 1970s until 1991 (late Boomers and their immediate successors being the relevant populations) and have since been falling to well below the rates of the early 1970s, on the order of 40 percent lower.24 Whatever the moral content of having sex early might be, modern teenagers seem to be more responsible about it than the Boomers. This is certainly due to better sex education, but neither sex ed nor contraceptives were unknown to the Boomers; how could they be, given the huge media attention given to court decisions legalizing prophylactics? If the Boomers could cook up LSD tabs by the thousands and establish “people’s stores” to distribute free marijuana, the exertions and embarrassments of buying a condom were surely not beyond them. That failure wasn’t just a product of the callowness of youth or the ignorance of the time. Rates of STD infection have been growing vastly faster among older (Boomer) Americans over the past several years than in the population as a whole, a fact tastefully overlooked in the pastoral commercials for Cialis.25 If natural firmness of purpose has proved fleeting, sexual recklessness has not.

Again, the inherent morality of Boomer sexuality matters less than its transgressiveness and consequences. The simple fact is that premarital sex and numerous partners were exercises in personal gratification and, given public opinion during the Boomers’ youth, distinctly against the social grain. That raises questions of sociopathy, answered by prevalence of Boomer abortion and infection. Both were easy enough to avoid. Failing to do so, as many Boomers did, indicates irresponsibility and, as to unsafe sex, a disregard for the safety of others. And the Boomers were unusually prone to these behaviors compared to their parents and children.

The Much-Married Divorcée

Decisions are made on the spur of the moment,
without forethought and without consideration
for the consequences to self or others; this may
lead to sudden changes of… relationships…

incapacity for mutually intimate relationships…

They may be irresponsible as parents.…

—DSM-V26

Perhaps not unrelated to the sexual revolution was the growing phenomenon of divorce, whose prevalence rose rapidly from the late 1960s. Part—but only part—of this new trend was due to the liberalization of divorce laws, which had been highly restrictive. For most of its history, the Christian West made divorce exceedingly difficult, so that on the eve of Parliament’s reforms in 1857, only 324 divorces had been recorded in England (Henry VIII accounted for just one of these, the rest of his marriages being curtailed by execution, natural death, or annulment).27 Colonial America adopted the motherland’s restrictions, with a given divorce often requiring specific act by a state legislature.

When jurisdiction migrated to the courts, divorces became easier but not easy, so that until the 1960s, a petitioner still had to demonstrate “fault” rather than simple incompatibility, with the bar set at abandonment, adultery, cruelty, or permanent insanity. A spouse opposing divorce could contest fault by the rather extraordinary practice of showing that the other side was equally guilty (i.e., “I did it but so did you”), which had the perverse effect of forcing couples who were mutually adulterous, cruel, and, theoretically, even completely insane, to stay together. Spouses could and did collude to work the system, with one falsely alleging cruelty and the other admitting to it, a strategy that while effective required no little perjury. The whole system was unworkable and in 1969, California pioneered “no-fault” divorces, which allowed spouses to part based solely on irreconcilable differences. This law was signed by then governor Ronald Reagan, whose own divorce had paved the way to union with Nancy (or “Mommy,” as he took to calling her).28

Easier divorce was certainly a social good—and one pioneered by earlier generations, not the Boomers. The frequency with which Boomers resorted to divorce, however, proved alarming and generationally unusual. It suggested some combination of growing impulsivity about entering a union, unwillingness to expend the effort necessary to make relationships work, and perhaps a fundamental incompatibility between an antisocial Boomer culture and the state of matrimony which, after all, is a society of two. Rates of divorce increased rapidly from the late 1960s onward, reaching a peak in 1980 (22.6 per 1,000 married women annually and on a largely downward trend since).29 Some of this was no more than the system processing the large inventory of unhappy couples who could suddenly take advantage of liberalized divorce laws. Yet some of this was a Boomer predisposition to divorce. Looking at marriages at comparable points in time, Boomers—especially older Boomers—divorced much more frequently than their parents and their children.30

While divorce overall declined and then stabilized, it has been growing rapidly among Americans over fifty, that is, heavily among Boomers, with rates doubling from 1990 to 2010.31 Doubtless, this is a product of Americans living much longer than before—as an institution, marriage may be ancient, but before the twentieth century, its participants rarely were. Nevertheless, Boomers divorce more than their elders did at comparable ages.32 This, too, suggests a degree of sociopathic inability to “form lasting relationships.”

The consequences of divorce also point in a sociopathic direction. Divorce is expensive: It is emotionally traumatic, the proceedings are costly, and it tends to decrease economic security for everyone involved. While divorce can have real benefits, they are often not equally distributed. William Strauss and Neil Howe, writing a quarter century ago, noted that “four-fifths of… divorced adults profess[ed] to being happier afterward… but a majority of their children fe[lt] otherwise.”33 It was the perception that children paid the highest price for divorce that prompted many pre-Boomer couples to stay together “for the children,” as the old cliché goes. In 1962, half of women believed parents in bad marriages should stay married for a child’s benefit. By 1980, when Boomers made up a substantial part of the survey pool, only 20 percent held that view.34 During the heyday of Boomer divorce, in the late 1970s and 1980s, there was a widespread belief that children from “broken homes” were destined to experience permanent damage. Recent research casts some doubts on that belief, even suggesting that divorce can be a net benefit for children of the most dysfunctional marriages. However, that research emerged after the divorce rate began to fall. And although the effects of divorce on children do not appear as bad as once thought, they still have notably negative effects in the short term, and for a minority of children these effects can be long lasting.36 Many Boomer divorces, therefore, were examples of self-interest trumping empathy, where the interests of parents outweighed the as-then-understood needs of their children.* Moreover, divorced Boomers are four times as likely to be poor and have disabilities as married Boomers. Doubtless, causation is mixed here, though the net effect is not. Further, the gray divorcé(e) phenomenon has its own challenges. As one set of researchers put it, “the rise in later life divorce may ultimately place additional burdens on society at large, as divorced individuals will be forced to turn to institutional (i.e., government) support,” and to the extent children/ex-spouses “cannot be called on to serve as caregivers,” this can reduce “intergenerational” happiness.37 Thus, even adult children whose parents are still married may, by the mechanisms of welfare and the national debt, end up suffering the consequences of Boomer broken homes. The system of Boomer marriages and divorces fits sociopathic archetypes, a pattern of relationships impulsively entered and dissolved, preference trumping duty. Not many divorcées are sociopaths, but a great many sociopaths get divorced.

Boomer vs. Boomer: The Divorce Generation

What’s going on here? Divorces became more common as obtaining them became easier, but this was not a one-way trend. This chart shows the number of men who married and remained so at their tenth anniversary, and the trend for women was understandably quite similar. (The median age for marriage in this entire period was 23–26.) While the Census doesn’t keep close track of marriages, the marriage success rates for the core Boomers do appear notably lower than those of generations born before and after.35

Instant Gratification and Postponed Consequences

A pattern of impulsivity may be manifested
by a failure to plan ahead…

—DSM-V38

Deficits in self-control were not limited to the sexual and marital. Perhaps the purest example of self-control and foresight is saving, the denial of pleasure now in favor of security later. This proved almost impossible for the Boomers, whose inability to save represented yet another radical break from earlier generations’ practices and ultimately required them to plunder the accounts of other generations.

The Boomers’ parents had been relentless savers, and as they reached their peak earning years in the early 1970s, they drove the savings rate up, briefly over 13 percent.39 As the Boomers came to represent a larger fraction of economic activity, the savings rate slid downward from 1975 until it reached its absolute low of 1.9 percent in July 2005. Though improved after the chaos of 2008, savings languished around 6 percent, or about half the rate of the period from 1959 to 1975. It’s not that incomes were so constrained after 1975 that it became impossible to save. It’s that the Boomers simply chose not to save nearly as much as their parents, as individuals or as a society.* We will delve into details and consequences in later chapters.

The Ant, the Grasshopper, and the Boomer

What’s going on here? Private savings have been in decline since the Boomers entered their prime working years. Because very little cohort data exists, economists debate exactly why the savings rate has declined—questioning whether the wealth effect of stock market bubbles discouraged the rich from saving in the 1990s, the natural tendency of a modestly aging population to dissave, and so on. But during the period of steep savings decline, the Boomers had major influence on the savings rate and should have been aggressive savers, yet the inexorable direction was down, until the crash of 2008 forced people to save more. The fact that many Boomers have relatively little net worth compared to their retirement needs (data we do have on a cohort basis) also tests the idea that lower income savings could be offset by gains in homes and stocks, though these assets have been prone to bubbles the Boomers have been keen to inflate.40

Failures in impulse control also manifested in gluttony. As American travelers know, and Europeans delight in observing, the United States is an unusually heavy place. This is so measured against international peers and against America itself, at least the America of sixty years ago. Relatively few adults were obese before the 1960s, about one in ten. Since then, adult obesity has been increasing, with a sharp rise from 12.7 percent in the late 1970s to 36.4 percent by 2011–2014.41 Younger generations are also now heavy, with the shift occurring in the 1980s and 1990s, though there have been some recent improvements.

Doubtless, some thickening was just a function of age; America has been getting older and older people tend toward, in Wilkie Collins’s memorable phrase, an “autumnal exuberance of figure.” It’s only a partial excuse. Europe and Japan have much older populations and nothing like the same level of obesity.42 And in the period in which American obesity rose most quickly, one in which the large group of Boomers had the greatest influence on national statistics and culture, the Boomers were not autumnal, they were at most midspring, and raising the first generations of fairly heavy American children. Predictably, the Boomers’ autumns are proving unusually ample, even relative to the relaxed standards of old age. From 1999 to 2002, 31.6 percent of men aged sixty-five to seventy-four (none of whom were Boomers) were obese, and by 2011–2014, when the group was essentially all Boomer, the rate was 41.5 percent; women of comparable ages increased slightly, from 39 percent to 40.3 percent, having experienced greater gains a few years earlier than men.43 Obesity rates among eighteen-to twenty-seven-year-olds recently (non-Boomers) also rose dramatically over the past decades, though obesity figures for nonseniors have remained relatively constant since 1999.44 Overall, the Boomers gained weight faster than prior generations and continued gaining weight, while younger generations appear to have at least stabilized at a new unhealthy normal.45

The Boomers did and continue to eat too much, and too poorly, and while junk food isn’t blameless, it also isn’t entirely to blame (this should be self-evident, though given Boomer proclivities to relocate blame, it needs discussion). Junk food has existed for a long time, in America and abroad. What did not exist, in America past or Europe present, was a set of consumers so susceptible to the joys of immediate gratification and so regularly seduced into its pursuit by the Boomers’ other major unhealthy consumable, ad-driven television. The consequence of this indiscipline has been a tide of ill health, from diabetes to heart disease. The pleasures of overconsumption, of course, were entirely personal. The costs have been socialized in the form of rising medical expenditures borne by the state and more temperate members of the risk pool, an irritating leitmotif in the Boomers’ sociopathic symphony.46

Me, Myself, and I

Compelling as sex, food, and spending were for the sociopath, nothing could match the pure pleasure of Self. This was only one of many generational oddities Tom Wolfe identified way back in the 1970s, in his “Me Decade” essay on the young Boomers.47 Carried to extremes, self-obsession is inherently antisocial, as every man (pace John Donne) becomes his own island, indifferent to the needs and concerns of others.

Indeed, self-focus would become a primary motivation of the Boomers’ neoliberal reforms after 1980, where retention of income took precedence over its partial redistribution and investment for social purposes. While there’s no way to precisely measure self-obsession on a national scale, shifts in language provide a reasonable guide. As the Boomers influenced culture, the plural evolved into the singular: “We Shall Overcome” (first recorded c. 1952), the anthem of civil rights solidarity, became by 1965 “(I Can’t Get No) Satisfaction,” the hymn of the singular hedonist. (Let’s dispense with the old saw that the latter tune critiques consumerism—the lyrics only passingly condemn ads before skipping on to the usual Boomer obsession with sex and, anyway, the Rolling Stones licensed the rights for $4 million for use in a Snickers commercial, rolling up junk food, fornication, TV, and cognitive dissonance into one perfect Boomer song/snack package.)48

As it was in songs, so it was in books, surveys of which show use of “we” declining somewhat since 1960, suggesting a faltering sense of community. Use of “I” has been increasing for forty years, accelerating dramatically in the late 1980s to rates in 2008 about 42 percent higher than in 1960, suggesting a rising degree of self-focus.*,49 “You” has also enjoyed a heyday, with usage tripling over the same period. The second person pronoun is a more ambiguous indicator than the first, but University of California, San Diego professor Jean Twenge, a persuasive and thorough researcher into these trends, speculates that “you” acts as a marker of individualism by separating the actor from the audience (in contrast to “we,” which is strongly inclusive).50 As the pronoun chart collapsed into the singular, so other parts of language were reoriented, powerless before the gravity of the selfhood singularity. Thus, “give” made way for “get,” and so on.51 For a sense of what effects these changes in language and conception might have on politics, one need not reach for Sapir, Whorf, and Wittgenstein. Just rewrite a Churchillian fragment in Boomerese: “We make a life by what we give” “I make a life by what I get.”

Down with the Opposition!

Individuals with antisocial personality disorder tend to
be irritable and aggressive and may repeatedly get into
physical fights or commit acts of physical assault.

—DSM-V52

It’s worth dwelling on one other feature of the individualist revolution: its reliance on illegal and often violent means. The draft avoidance of Vietnam, as we’ve seen, had motivations where personal benefit was at least as important as political change, and its methods ran the gamut from legal (if questionable) deferments to the patently criminal. Another illegal strategy—one whose political instantiation would form the core of Boomer neoliberal policy—was refusing to pay taxes. Some failed to remit only the temporary 10 percent tax enacted as part of war policy, which while self-serving and illegal was at least tailored to the political issue; others, like the singer Joan Baez (who provided some theme music to antiwar protests), refused to pay the majority of their bills, even though at most a quarter or so went to defense and the rest to benign enterprises like the War on Poverty (apparently, “antiwar” was a fairly expansive concept). The widespread manufacture, distribution, and use of recreational drugs was, of course, also plainly illegal, and more aggressive and less successful than the efforts of later generations to legalize marijuana through the conventional political process.

Far more troubling was the violence sometimes used by the white middle class. The Sixties riots in black neighborhoods like Watts and Compton had origins in the nation’s original sins of slavery and racism; if the reactions were violent, so were the provocations. Some draft misconduct can be justified under the same logic, though only some. It is much harder to construct redeeming explanations for some of the extreme tactics and muddled motivations employed in college demonstrations, which were usually the work of privileged students distant from the chaos of the jungle and the police state of the ghettoes. Even on their own terms, these demonstrations involved a certain amount of contradiction, with violence being deployed to protest violence. Protestors might have chuckled about the infamous military statement that “it became necessary to destroy the town to save it,” even as their own conduct embodied the same woolliness.

The Columbia University riots of 1968 embodied all these themes. In the riots, white students (led by the perhaps misleadingly named Students for a Democratic Society) were dismissive of the black community’s specific concerns and objectives, even though a key feature of the white protest was distaste for Columbia’s dismissiveness of the black community’s concerns regarding development plans in Harlem. The black students disapproved of the white group’s more aggressive tactics and the opportunistic use of the development issue as a springboard for a wider protest against the war. This deterred the white group not one bit. Exhibiting the same Anglo paternalism they were decrying in class (when they cared to attend), white students wanted what they wanted and would use whatever means they deemed appropriate, taking over university buildings, destroying property, taking Dean Henry Coleman as a hostage (until the black students apparently let him leave the next day) and generally escalating matters well beyond the narrow issue of Harlem development. All this was undertaken, mind you, in the name of peace and cross-racial understanding.53

Outside the university, political violence found greatest expression in Chicago, home of the 1968 Democratic National Convention. The Yippies, a youth party, threatened to kidnap delegates, taint the water supply with LSD, and otherwise sow chaos—the epitome of antisocial behavior.*,54 The results were entirely predictable. The police got aggressive, the protestors reacted by throwing rocks, and the establishment went berserk. The Yippie platform stood for anarchy, and anarchy they got. Dozens on both sides were injured. The protestors got the worst of it, and not just physically—the practical result of the riots was not an anarcho-socialist utopia but a debacle that helped convince the public that law-and-order Dick Nixon was just the ticket.55

A cranky observation by the old about the young: They just don’t make ’em like the used to. In the case of the Boomers versus their parents, the statement is depressingly true. Boomers were more promiscuous, divorced more frequently, had more abortions, saved less, ate more, had more problems with authority, and so on. The statement is true, in a more consoling way, in the case of the Boomers versus their own children. Younger generations divorce less frequently and seem to be saving more. They do have sex somewhat earlier, but they are less promiscuous overall and significantly more responsible, with rates of teenage and unwanted pregnancies declining (the exception being in some minority communities for reasons beyond this book’s scope).56

Only on matters of narcissism and self-focus are generations younger than the Boomers noticeably worse, though the Boomers get credit for kicking off the trend. It’s true that the absolute rate of some problems remains high relative to those experienced by the very oldest living generations, but as we’ve seen, at least younger groups are moving in encouraging directions. Even the supposed acme of youthful self-absorption, the use of electronics at the dinner table, it turns out, is more a Boomer than a Millennial habit, and if Boomers can’t manage to pin dinnertime tech violations on the Millennials, maybe young people today are better than seniors think.57

The Boomers remained steadfast in their dysfunction. These antisocial tendencies matter, because when Boomers ascended to government, personality quirks would transmute into national policy. The phylogeny of the personal—profligate, indulgent, and irresponsible—would be recapitulated in the ontogeny of the political, as neoliberalism.

CHAPTER SIX

DISCO AND THE ROOTS OF NEOLIBERALISM

We have always known that heedless self-interest was
bad morals; we know now that it is bad economics.

—Franklin Roosevelt (1937)1

Everybody thinks of economics whether he is aware of it or not.
In joining a political party and in casting his ballot, the citizen
implicitly takes a stand upon essential economic theories.

—Ludwig von Mises (1940)2

One could be forgiven for dismissing the 1970s as a best-forgotten waiting room between the youthful rebellions of the 1960s and the Reaganite glitz of the 1980s. The shag and the stagflation, the fleeting presidencies of the crook, the bumbler, and the peanut farmer, the space station that fell out of the sky above and the mania for Pong down below; it’s hard to take the disco decade seriously. But lurking beneath the ephemeral tackiness lay a profound reordering of priorities, a process that was tentative, moderate, and even reasonable at first before it became increasingly, sociopathically unhinged in line with the Boomers’ growing political power.

The faltering of an economy previously so good at delivering mass prosperity made some changes inevitable. The Seventies’ combination of slow growth and high inflation were held by conventional models to be impossible, and when the impossible happened, the models were understandably at a loss. Then again, the models weren’t prepared for the novel combinations of the 1970s: the new phenomena of oil crises, odd agricultural complications, sloppy monetary policy, and the sudden influx of millions of Boomers, including new “career women,” all looking for jobs. Nevertheless, the old system proved fairly resilient. Though economic conditions of the Seventies may have been the worst since the Great Depression, they were not so bad in absolute terms: living standards continued to rise and performance was better, overall, than it would be in subsequent recessions.

Given that the Seventies were a time of moderate difficulty, you might have predicted an equally moderate response, and for a time, that’s what the country got. Unfortunately, these conventional strategies could not bring inflation under control and the Fed, under Chairman Paul Volcker, led a dramatic and successful intervention from 1980 to 1982. Volcker hiked interest rates dramatically, prompting a sharp recession that helped tame inflation. With the inflationary threat eliminated and the old system’s long and otherwise successful legacy, the natural path for further reform was incremental, not revolutionary. Even if substantial changes were on the table, they might be expected (given conventional understandings of Sixties sanctimony) to take the form of new commitments to the parts of the old program that worked well, like civil rights and environmental legislation, the reform of programs with mixed but generally positive results, like welfare, and renewed commitments to the fiscal restraint and investment priorities that had worked in the 1950s and 1960s but seemed in danger of lapsing.

The seemingly least likely choice was what actually happened, a heterodox revolution that took the worst elements of older programs and combined them into a bizarre “neoliberal” agenda that featured an economy simultaneously laissez-faire and heavily dependent on state spending and occasional federal bailouts; a conservative government, yet one with radical ideals; a rhetoric of probity, but a policy of total fiscal and other indiscipline; Republicans overseeing government bloat while Democrats promoted free trade and the “end of welfare as we know it.” It was ideologically incoherent and it didn’t work particularly well, not for many Americans. But—the critical “but”—it did work well for one group, and that group would be the most powerful voting constituency during neoliberalism’s long reign: the Boomers.

Just as the Boomers cannot be fully understood without knowing something about Dr. Spock and Vietnam, so their policies cannot be comprehended without understanding neoliberalism. Neoliberal doctrine serves as the operating system of Boomer dominance and is so pervasive and damaging that it requires a chapter of its own. Many of the American policy calamities of the past decades have, as their animating source, some perverted fragment of neoliberal doctrine.*

Neoliberalism 1.0

A key feature of Boomer sociopathy is maximizing present consumption regardless of future costs, so reshaping the economy would be the focus of the revolutionary project. This proceeded under a set of theories, political and economic, now known as neoliberalism. Boomer neoliberalism isn’t true neoliberalism (the latter is at least coherent)—the Boomer version is more free market à la carte, as we’ll see.

Understanding Boomer neoliberalism requires an appreciation of the original doctrine and its flaws, in the same way that if one wants to recreate a Roman republic or Leninist paradise, it helps to know about the gladiators, slaves, gulags, and show trials. The “paleo-” liberalism that preceded the “neo-” version was classical liberalism, which dominated Anglophone policy from the Industrial Revolution to the Great Depression. Liberalism’s Jurassic incarnation emphasized a “slim” state, in which individuals could do as they pleased and the government did a dead minimum, limiting itself to arbitration of disputes, national defense, and the supply of a few public works like the post. Everything else was superfluous, with Austrian-American liberal Ludwig von Mises, a later exponent, opining (in 1927, two years before the Great Crash) that the “task of the state consists solely and exclusively in guaranteeing the protection of life, health, liberty, and private property against violent attacks. Everything that goes beyond this is an evil.”3

Liberalism viewed government as an umpire with a gun, one to be fired only in cases of the most obvious emergency. The state did not need to stimulate the economy in a depression, concern itself with the poor, establish a minimum wage, ban child labor, keep toxins out of streams, or really, much of anything. For ultraliberals, any interventions would be both immoral (von Mises wasn’t just being poetic in using the term “evil”) and pointless. Nothing could organize the market better than itself; any intervention, by definition, would reduce total utility.*,4 Unfettered capitalism was Dr. Pangloss’s best of all possible worlds. Liberalism in its purist form and in aspiration—though not practical instantiation—remains relevant as the capitalist utopia to which diehards desperately seek a return; it is the (ostensible) omega point of the modern neoliberal revolution. This is what the various neoliberal acolytes (the saints Paul: Ryan, Rand, Ron) are excited about, smacked on the head by Atlas Shrugged on their roads to Washington.

The Depression created a certain inconvenience for liberalism, since its best counsel was to stand by while quasi-Darwinian forces brought the system around. Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon supposedly advised the government that the appropriate response to the Depression was to “liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate… it will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people.”5 This may have endeared Mellon to Ayn Rand, but not to the enfranchised multitude.

Hoover and Mellon did more than history gives them credit for (i.e., they did more than absolutely nothing) and it’s never been clear if Mellon actually called for anyone to be “liquidated.” None of that mattered, because by the election of 1932, the market was clearly not healing itself. The other parts of Adam Smith’s hand might have been invisible, but the position of its middle digit could be easily detected.

Americans therefore elected Franklin Roosevelt to pursue a more aggressive course. The electorate felt the poor deserved shelter, the jobless yearned for work, the bankers needed regulation, and the Hobbesian securities market needed its Leviathan; these, Roosevelt supplied. Roosevelt’s policies helped, as did a monetary expansion that came from an odd combination of a falling dollar and the simultaneous flow of funds out of a destabilizing Europe and into the safety of the United States.* The economy began growing, though by the end of the 1930s it still had not reached its pre-Depression levels and unemployment remained high.

What was missing was stimulus on a truly Keynesian scale, in no small part because John Maynard Keynes himself was, for American purposes, also missing. The New Deal, which began in 1933, gets cast as a Keynesian enterprise but it was not, at least not initially or intentionally. Keynes published his first work on depressions in 1933, didn’t meet Roosevelt until 1934, and didn’t put out his masterwork, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, until 1936. As it happened, FDR’s policies of regulation and poor relief overlapped in substantial part with Keynesianism, even if those policies didn’t quite go as far as Keynes might have liked. This disconnect meant the New Deal was not a perfect experiment and that has caused no end of political trouble. For ultra–free marketers, the New Deal was not really Keynesian (sort of true) and this was a blessing, because it meant FDR’s meddling merely delayed, rather than derailed, the inevitable recovery (less true). For the Keynesians, the New Deal was a success but could have been more successful still, had FDR pushed as far as theory demanded (plausible). My own view is that the New Deal and its successors were neither Keynesian nor not-Keynesian, but rather wholly American: pragmatic responses to specific problems informed by, but never slavish to, theory.

In the twenty-first century, it may seem a bit stale to reexamine the policies of a time so distant that the champion of the masses was fond of wearing a cape and top hat, but the debate over how the Depression ended remains immensely relevant. After all, the Great Recession, which in many ways began in 2001, has never quite been banished, and people still argue about regulation, stimulus, bailouts, and trade. The Great Depression and Great Recession are not perfect analogues, but they are comparable. Because we cannot run controlled experiments, comprehending what got the economy moving during the 1930s and then kept it going for another four decades is one reasonable way to understand what might work now and in the future.*

Mutant Neoliberalism

Following the Great Depression, classical liberalism seemed dead: Everyone conceded a broader role for the state, and the essential question was about the right amount of intervention. Unlike the modern debate we will shortly take up, this midcentury dialogue was fruitful. The Keynesian Left argued that the modern economy was prone to problems only the state could address. The original neoliberal Right argued that too much intervention would produce a sclerotic, ever-expanding welfare state, as it indeed would in pre-Thatcher Britain. Each doctrine provided useful correction to the other. Unfortunately, neither view was sociopathically optimal. The original Keynesianism went two ways—not only did the state have a role in stimulating the economy, it also had an obligation to tamp speculation and bubbles. Since that implied occasional curbs on consumption, it was unacceptable to the sociopathic mind. As for neoliberalism, it was not only ideologically impure, which was incompatible with the sociopath’s distaste for nuance, the theory also didn’t provide as many attractive social benefits and was irritatingly obsessed with fiscal restraint.

Even as the original neoliberalism developed, the purists assembled their forces. Influential thinkers like von Mises as well as Friedrich Hayek, Karl Popper, and Milton Friedman founded the Mont Pelerin Society to fight for laissez-faire.* Per its website, Society members saw—and still saw as of this book’s printing—“danger in the expansion of government, not least in state welfare, in the power of trade unions and business monopoly, and in the continuing threat and reality of inflation.”6 Despite the Society’s obscurity—a search of the New York Times archives produces only a handful of references, with more about the resort than the Society itself—it has nevertheless been exceedingly influential. Pelerin has included eight Nobelists in economics and in 1970 added to its rolls Charles Koch, the billionaire who has underwritten much of the conservative movement.7 If Koch’s money failed to produce results when allied to feckless nonentities like Marco Rubio, when combined with heft like Pelerin’s, it produced results. After the debacle of 2008, the reason why there was any debate at all about stimulus and the risks of inflation (at a time when the country was flirting with deflation) is because of groups like Pelerin.

Obviously, given that neoliberals themselves struggle over what their doctrine means, the term has been slippery, operating as a sort of economic Rorschach blob that reveals more about its viewer than itself. For many Leftists, “neoliberal” is just a polite term for capitalism rampant, a doctrine that leads straight from Ronald Reagan to the dystopia of Blake’s satanic mills, operated by enslaved child laborers and belching soot and inequality. For the Right, it is simply a label with no content, as the various subgroups prefer to organize themselves as “Austrians” (after the country that produced Hayek, von Mises, and others) or “Chicago School” (the home of Milton Friedman, et al.), etc.

For everyone else, including the critical group of politicians that counts among its members every president since Reagan and relies on the doctrine, neoliberalism boils down to this: Individuals are best suited to take care of themselves, and therefore the default position is that government has no role. Or, anyway, as we’ll see, no role until the right kind of individuals make the wrong kinds of decisions and need a little refreshment in the form of federal funds.

Regardless of the school, every variety of neoliberalism depends upon key and problematic assumptions: that individuals are rational, prudent, and informed, and that they therefore can be relied upon to meet their own needs. Most economic theories rely on these assumptions, but few to the degree that neoliberalism does. However, a large body of work, especially by Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman, shows that humans are not wholly rational agents, that we are susceptible to numerous cognitive biases that drive our thinking away from the rational idea. These biases lurk in normal people, but sociopaths operate at even greater remove from the rational ideal, prey to needs for immediate gratification, fond of risk, and unable to plan for the future. Neoliberalism requires Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill’s homo economicus, the rational individual optimizing among his economic choices, but at best gets flawed homo sapiens, and from the 1970s on, must content itself with the Boomers’ homo sociopathicus. The results have not been good.

The various problems of neoliberalism remained concealed for some time, because the New Deal’s success mooted the doctrine. The adjustments of the New Deal set a popular baseline for government intervention. More importantly, for decades, the economy grew and delivered mass prosperity despite (for the neoliberals) or because of (for everyone else) a government that operated a social safety net, invested heavily in physical and educational infrastructure, tolerated labor organizations, intervened in trade, stimulated the economy from time to time, and maintained reasonable budget discipline including through high taxes. For years, no influential politician embraced the full neoliberal agenda, nor did citizens demand such.

Only in two areas, fiscal responsibility and a strong dollar, did conservative ideas retain any real sway, with generally good results. World War II made balanced budgets impossible, but the following twenty years saw a concerted attempt to reduce deficits and bring down debt. These efforts were not entirely successful, because of the expense of social programs, military outlays, and Eisenhower’s enormous infrastructure programs. Still, the government did make substantial progress toward a balanced budget, and the federal debt became much less burdensome. Stimulus was provided (and less frequently, withdrawn) to moderate the business cycle, but any large deficits stimulus engendered were to be tolerated only in the short term, not as the permanent fixture they have become.

As for the dollar, strength was maintained by a fixed link between gold and the dollar ($35 per ounce) and between the dollar and other currencies by the Bretton Woods exchange system. In theory, if you were concerned about the value of the dollar, you could simply go up to the Gold Window and exchange $35 for one ounce of gold, though in practice only foreign governments did this and usually through the account books. These constraints kept the greenback from depreciating, preserving purchasing power. For conservatives, a balanced budget and a strong dollar were not only good economic policy, they were the instantiations of morality itself. Unfortunately, these antique notions restrained consumption and would prove an insurmountable obstacle to the adoption of neoliberal (or neo-neo-liberal) policies by the Boomers. Until the late 1960s, however, they commanded the support of the people and governments of both parties.

So liberalism, neo-and otherwise, had to bide its time as a theory waiting for an audience. Before the 1970s, there was only one credible attempt to advance anything like liberalism, and then only in its Jurassic form. The failure of that campaign suggested the future compromises necessary to get the rest of the neoliberal agenda in place. The 1964 presidential race, between Johnson and Goldwater, provided the forum. In dramatic contrast to Johnson, Goldwater had no patience for any of the government programs or fiscal indiscipline that had despoiled the capitalist landscape. He said as much in his election-year book, The Conscience of a Conservative. More than the standard and ephemeral election-year reminisce, Conscience shaped the entire conservative movement and remains sufficiently powerful that Paul Krugman, an advocate for government’s ability to solve problems, Nobel Prize–winning economist, and New York Times columnist, titled his 2007 book Conscience of a Liberal, something of a riposte to a book written more than forty years before. Even the Democratic nominee of 2016, Hillary Clinton, had been a Goldwater supporter and as late as 1996 attributed certain of her political beliefs to those conservative early days.*,8

The third way was not Goldwater’s; he hewed instead to the classical liberal position, demanding that government butt out as a matter of both sound economics and morality. In his view, the government could participate in the economy only in the exercise of its “legitimate” functions, as explicitly set forth in the Constitution.9 The Constitution, however, doesn’t exactly dwell either specifically or at length about most of the activities of the modern state—which was Goldwater’s point. Aside from a few things like establishing a military and post office, the Constitution spends most of its length on the mechanics of federal office holding. Crucially, however, its language is flexible to allow for a wide range of powers—as Roosevelt decisively established, albeit by coercive means, in legal cases testing the New Deal before the Supreme Court. Therefore, Goldwater would have to convince people as a political, rather than legal, matter that the nation had drifted into unconstitutional waters. His and other conservatives’ failure to do so explains the hard Right’s fixation since the 1980s with controlling the courts, to achieve by judicial means what politics could not.

Brandishing the Constitution, Goldwater informed the American people that programs like Social Security, farm regulation, and labor relations appear nowhere within the Constitution, and asked for a mandate to abolish them all. As for taxes, anything beyond the amounts necessary to fund “legitimate” operations were to be eliminated. What taxes did remain, Goldwater believed, should be flat instead of progressive (i.e., everyone should pay the same percentage, rather than higher earners paying a larger fraction).10 Even the infrastructure programs and modest welfare programs Eisenhower presided over were “disappointing” in their profligacy and extent, to say nothing of what Johnson proposed.11 As to that, Goldwater viewed Johnson’s Great Society as an expressway to communist hell, paved with food stamps and educational subsidies. “Socialism can be achieved through Welfarism,” Goldwater asserted, perhaps viewing Johnson’s war in Vietnam as nothing more than a squabble among communist fellow travelers.12

The senator’s message didn’t resonate, at least, not with most of the electorate, not at the time. Johnson trounced Goldwater in 1964, with 61 percent of the popular vote to 39 percent, capturing every region of the country except Goldwater’s home state and—this would be crucial—the deep South. In part, Goldwater was seen as dangerously aggressive and willing to consider tactical nuclear bombing in Vietnam. (An infamous Johnson attack ad played to these fears by cutting from a shot of a little girl picking flower petals to footage of a mushroom cloud going up.) But the senator’s social and economic vision probably undid him as much as or more than the saber rattling, as Goldwater himself should have predicted when reading the book his ghostwriter had prepared, which repeatedly emphasized (and deplored) “Welfarism’s strong emotional appeal to many voters.”13 Regardless, if Goldwater’s views of fifty years ago seem oddly fresh, it’s because they provide much of the motivating doctrine of the modern Right. Goldwater may have lost in 1964 but many of his views prevail today, with a few critical modifications.

Before the Goldwater candidacy could evolve into the Reagan presidency, it had to contend with one last champion of big government, Richard Nixon. Nixon’s pro-government legacy has been obscured by Watergate and by certain Leftists’ unnuanced disgust, but personal failings notwithstanding, it was the Republican Nixon who favored a government bigger than anything Clinton (either one) or Barack Obama dared propose, promoting domestic policies we would now view as unambiguously Leftist, so much so that even Noam Chomsky called him “in many respects, the last liberal president.”14

Whether Nixon truly believed in big government, pursued it because it flattered his imperial grandiosity, or was simply engaging in political strategy, the fact remains that he hugely increased government’s remit in American lives. He did so despite his loathing of the Washington bureaucracy, the poor, minorities (and really, everyone). Under Nixon, an already sizable government grew to the point where almost no aspect of American life remained untouched. Nixon helped regulate the environment through legislation and by establishing the Environmental Protection Agency. He supported safer working conditions by creating the Occupational Safety and Health Administration. He proposed health-care reform, suggesting expansion of state-administered programs to offer insurance to all Americans, which—Obamacare notwithstanding—remains a dream unfulfilled. With the Fair Labor Standards Act, he increased the minimum wage, and he supported the Equal Rights Amendment, which would have helped ensure wage parity between men and women. Even the arts, the habitat of pinko intellectuals Nixon so detested, received enormous increases in federal funding. Perhaps his boldest idea was to scrap welfare in favor of a guaranteed minimum income for all Americans, an experiment so radical that it has never been adopted by any major nation. Congress killed the idea, but it was a bold one and got surprisingly far, further than in any other until the Swiss picked up (then dropped) the idea in the twenty-first century.15

Nixon therefore represented the high-water mark of the big state, a world where government could solve problems rather than simply being the problem. But the old order soon fell, a victim of a series of crises that individually could have been absorbed but collectively proved temporarily overwhelming, opening the door for neoliberalism. The first challenge was inflation and the dollar. By the late 1960s, the economic framework that had prevailed following World War II had, like everything else, begun to fray. Though the economy continued to expand, with employment and wage growth at levels we would today consider acceptable, heavy government spending on the war and social programs created inflationary pressures whose consequences would be the defining economic experience of the young Boomers.

The Deadly Chimera

Although Johnson had imposed temporary taxes to at least partly defray the costs of Vietnam (something Bush II wouldn’t repeat during Iraq II), these were too small to persuade the markets about Washington’s fiscal discipline; the financial community worried that bigger deficits would lead to inflation. Today, this would simply be reflected by a falling dollar in the foreign exchange market, but that was (formally) impossible before 1971, because the dollar was pegged to gold at $35 per ounce. And before the late 1960s, it didn’t need to be reflected in anything: Roughly balanced budgets created little fear of inflation, and any skeptics could simply exchange their dollars for gold, of which more than half the world’s supply was held by the United States.

The gold-dollar system had been the centerpiece of the Bretton Woods agreement, which required major trading nations to adhere to the gold standard and created institutions like the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank to manage the system. Bretton Woods had successfully lubricated the postwar global economy, but the system always had weaknesses (involving problems with the American current account too technical to delve into here), and it certainly could not withstand a permanent deviation between the official price of gold and the market’s views on what the real price should be. Johnson’s heavy spending on the Great Society and Vietnam convinced foreign holders that the real value of the dollar was falling, and they exchanged dollars for gold at the official, and in their view, artificially high, price.

As long as the United States held enough gold, it could maintain whatever fictive gold-dollar rate it wanted, but by the late 1960s, the United States was running low on gold and the system destabilized. The prospect of letting Bretton Woods go dismayed most leaders. Various and increasingly desperate measures were taken to keep the system going, including minor adjustments to the gold-dollar rate, price controls, and cajoling members into accepting losses on their dollar holdings. None of these tactics sufficed, and in August 1971, Nixon took the United States off the gold standard.

Conservatives have fumed about this ever since, because it meant the government really could just print as much money as it wanted, eroding the value of some assets. Of course, it matters who holds those inflation-sensitive assets, and when the Boomers joined the capitalist class, they were determined to strangle inflation regardless of the price to growth. The Boomers are perhaps the savviest generation about inflation since Weimar Germans, because they lived through periods of both high and low inflation and they know whom it can help and whom it can hurt. Inflation is to the Boomers what rain is to farmers; useful when sowing, dangerous when reaping, and always a subject of preoccupation. The 1970s provided Boomers with an invaluable education, and they would manipulate inflation policy in ruthless service of their own ends. But that would come later; in the meantime, the 1970s had other inflationary lessons.

To resume, with gold convertibility gone and no effective restraints left, the value of the dollar fell and inflation accelerated. The traditional response would have been to cool demand through some combination of lower spending and higher taxes. However, the economy had dipped very slightly, and Nixon wanted strong growth ahead of the 1972 election. Though nominally a conservative Republican, Nixon embraced Keynesian mechanisms (even if he never quite said, “We are all Keynesians now”). The president cajoled the Federal Reserve and Congress and ordered agencies under his control to spend as much as they could, a mandate the Defense Department fulfilled by buying a two-year supply of toilet paper.16 Grow the economy did, at the price of further inflation. It’s not clear the economy needed much stimulating in the first place, any more than Nixon needed Watergate shenanigans to secure his 1972 landslide, but Nixon liked overkill.

Between the Nixon stimulus, the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, Vietnam spending, and natural growth, the economy overheated and inflation accelerated. Compounding the problem were new “supply shocks” in the form of sudden rises in the price of essential commodities, especially oil and food. Oil was denominated in dollars, so a weakening dollar after the collapse of Bretton Woods lowered the incomes of the oil-producing nations. OPEC subsequently repriced oil in gold terms, which effectively raised the dollar price of oil. OPEC raised prices again in response to the Yom Kippur War. Following the peace of 1974, price growth decelerated until the Iranian Revolution of 1979, which sent prices even higher than the shocks of 1973. Prices abated over time, but the legacy remains in America’s enduring commitment to protecting Gulf oil supplies. It also lingers in the financialized economy the oil spikes helped produce. All those oil dollars, liberated from individual pockets, were concentrated and sent back to a limited number of American financial institutions, providing them with capital that would be deployed in the investment-banking economy that has prevailed since the 1980s.

The other major problem was unemployment, which was rising, albeit from the exceedingly low level of 3.9 percent in January 1970 to 5.1 percent just after the first oil shock, then rising substantially as recession set in. By 1979, it was back to 5.6 percent, before another oil shock wrought more havoc, but through the 1970s, conditions never quite achieved the same severity as what happened post-2008.17 It was a fairly good result considering the oil shocks, the large numbers of veterans returning to civilian employment after Vietnam, and the hordes of Boomers entering the workforce every year. But unemployment threatened the young Boomers most of all; the economy was simply not growing fast enough for them.

Youth unemployment is often higher than the general rate, and the 1970s were no different. The problem especially affected young, blue-collar workers. The United States was substantially more unionized then than now; some 20+ percent of workers were unionized versus 11.1 percent in 2014.*,18 The unions’ seniority rules preserved old workers’ jobs at the expense of the young, and this made the unemployment crisis among Boomers especially acute.

The whole mess was termed “stagflation,” and it seemed intractable. The conventional tack for slower growth would be stimulus, but stimulus would provoke inflation; the traditional response to control inflation would be to suppress growth, but growth was already suppressed. This left planners in a bind. In the end, they left monetary policy loose, risking higher inflation, which they got.

To repeat, however: The 1970s weren’t entirely terrible. Although the decade witnessed the (then) worst economic conditions since the Depression, things were nowhere near as bad as they were in the 1930s and not nearly as much of a lost decade for middle-income Americans as the 2000s and 2010s would be. Between 1970 and 1979, inflation and unemployment peaked at 13.5 percent and 9.0 percent, respectively.19 The economy continued to grow, averaging 3.2 percent real growth between 1970 and 1979, and the S&P 500 rose modestly, from 85 at the beginning of 1970 to 108 at the end of 1979. Most Boomers got jobs, and most of the jobs were good. The 1970s were also the last decade in which the working class experienced meaningful wage growth.20 While the economic dislocations of the 1970s were surely stressful and alarming, the economy’s overall performance was at worst mediocre—indeed, it was noticeably better than the period between 2000 and 2015, despite perhaps greater challenges overall, many either benign (a growing population of workers, i.e., Boomers) or exogenous (Iranian Revolution, etc.). Nevertheless, for a generation habituated to fast growth and high employment, the entire decade came as a shock.

What was to be done? As we’ve seen, there were three major options. Option 1: a revision of the existing Keynesian/New Deal/Great Society project—perhaps balancing budgets a bit better, making the economy less vulnerable to exogenous shocks like oil embargoes, maybe a little less regulation. Option 2: a return to the classical order that prevailed before the Depression. Option 3: neoliberal revolution. Each succeeding election provided opportunities for voters to choose a path, and every year, the Boomer component of the electorate grew and pushed politics further down the neoliberal path. In the long term, there could never have really been a question about which option would be chosen, for the only one that catered to sociopathic urges was Option 3.

The Boomers were not yet in control, and neither President Ford nor President Carter enjoyed a mandate for change. Given political stasis, the best that could be managed was a highly unconvincing Option 1. For his first year, Ford opted for a traditional economic package, trimming unnecessary spending, providing targeted stimulus, and raising taxes on corporations and higher earners to ensure some level of balance in the budget. The Republican even added a dash of New Deal, a Community Improvement Corps to hire the jobless for beautification projects if unemployment rose to over 6 percent. Ford also proposed stronger regulation, especially of antitrust laws, to avoid abusive practices.21 The fatal mistake, however, came when he asked the American people to voluntarily reduce consumption to help ease inflationary pressures. Ford’s proposals irritated an increasingly Boomerish America. Eventually, the president was forced into what his press secretary called a “179-degree turn.”22 Instead of going up, taxes were cut somewhat and spending increased. The budget did not balance, slipping in 1974–1975 from a deficit of –0.4 percent to –3.3 percent.23 Ford pleased no one, especially not diehards in the Republican Party, who were dismayed by the president’s failure to enact radical welfare cuts, his policy of détente with the Soviet Union, and his embrace of the Equal Rights Amendment. The Rightist National Review even called for the creation of a third party to challenge Ford in 1976 (forty years later, they would get their wish, more and less, with Trump). In 1976, there was no need, because Ronald Reagan was leading an insurrection from within the party, though the inertia of incumbency delivered the party’s nomination to Ford.

In the end Jimmy Carter narrowly prevailed, with just 50.1 percent of the vote. Carter’s proposals were as modest as his victory—balancing the budget, enacting a tiny tax cut in the form of a fifty-dollar rebate, and leaving the government mostly intact. His only truly significant economic initiative was deregulation, which had long been hoped for by conservatives. This began with airlines and trucking, whose prices were constrained by federal mandate. Early deregulation was generally good, especially when accompanied by vigorous enforcement of other standards—it’s one thing to deregulate the price of a plane ticket, it’s another thing to abolish the Federal Aviation Administration. They were also long-term reforms, which could not reasonably be expected to bear fruit for some time.

Something more immediate was required, and here is where Waterloo came to the White House, in the form of a 1979 address known as the Malaise Speech. Preparing for reelection, Jimmy Carter decided to be frank with the American people about the problems he saw, the last effort of a decent man to cajole the American people (by then, heavily composed of Boomers) into their former probity. The Malaise Speech is worth dwelling on because it is at once so correct as a diagnosis and so feckless as a political document, and quoted are its salient points (all italics mine):

• It’s clear that the true problems of our Nation are much deeper—deeper than gasoline lines or energy shortages, deeper even than inflation or recession.

• In a nation that was proud of hard work, strong families, close-knit communities, and our faith in God, too many of us now tend to worship self-indulgence and consumption.

• Human identity is no longer defined by what one does, but by what one owns.

• The willingness of Americans to save for the future has fallen below that of all other people in the Western world.

• As you know, there is a growing disrespect for government and for churches and for schools, the news media, and other institutions.

• These changes did not happen overnight. They’ve come upon us gradually over the last generation, years that were filled with shocks and tragedy.

• We simply must have faith in each other, faith in our ability to govern ourselves, and faith in the future of this Nation. Restoring that faith and that confidence to America is now the most important task we face. It is a true challenge of this generation of Americans.

• We are at a turning point in our history. There are two paths to choose. One is a path I’ve warned about tonight, the path that leads to fragmentation and self-interest. Down that road lies a mistaken idea of freedom, the right to grasp for ourselves some advantage over others. That path would be one of constant conflict between narrow interests ending in chaos and immobility. It is a certain route to failure.

• I do not promise you that this struggle for freedom will be easy. I do not promise a quick way out of our nation’s problems, when the truth is that the only way out is an all-out effort.24

You can almost hear the wheels of the presidential Pinto squealing right before it flew off the cliff. It’s not that Carter was wrong; he was simply proposing a return to the values that had worked so well before, getting at the root of a problem whose symptoms may have been stagflationary, but whose causes were behavioral and fundamental, even, Carter, hinted, “generation[al]” and maybe even the future responsibility of one generation in particular. However, while Carter was smart enough to diagnose the cause, he failed to appreciate the real implications of his message. The very people exhibiting the sociopathy he described were the ones least receptive to his prescriptions. More savings, less consumption? More trust, more family, less individualism, less self-interest? Hard work?

Carter didn’t fully understand the deep changes to the American demographic the Boomers had wrought, nor did he count on the emergence as a serious political figure of Ronald Reagan, the actor whose sidekick Bubbles the Chimp had been replaced by Art Laffer and his Magic Curve. Reagan (or, at least, the public’s version of him) was tailor-made for the sociopathic electorate. Never again would the Boomers be told to save, or adjust the thermostat, or define themselves other than by their material possessions, to work on their families, to trust a meddlesome government, to abandon the pursuit of unrestrained individualism, or to undertake an “all-out effort” of any kind. All problems would be resolved by neoliberalism, for once the decks had been cleared of encumbering regulation and the human bilge discharged from the holds of the welfare state, things would take care of themselves: growth, jobs, inflation, consumption, all of it.

The essence of Reagan’s message was paleoliberalism, but Goldwater had shown that paleoliberalism was a hard sell. The people liked many of the benefits big government handed out, so even if doctrine required their abolition, the most that could be done was shutting off the flow to the least telegenic recipients. The second obstacle was fiscal restraint. Sociopathic consumption demanded tax cuts, but it also demanded government largesse. Liberalist orthodoxy also required tax cuts, but insisted on a balanced budget. Reducing government spending on research, development, the arts, and so on could never offset the tax cuts being proposed, and reducing middle-class benefits was out of the question. The only option, therefore, was to tolerate huge deficits, until such time as Americans were prepared to do away with the big state.

In the meantime, to cultivate a patina of fiscal responsibility, Reagan turned to a new theory that held that tax cuts would pay for themselves. (Here’s where TV’s suspension of disbelief became crucial, both for the actor-president and for the voters who elected him.) The government would return dollars to the people, the people would use them more productively than the government, and the economy would grow so much that even at a lower tax rate it would provide as much or more in total taxes paid. This theory, instantiated in a graph now called the “Laffer Curve” and originally inscribed on a cocktail napkin (and presumably under the influence of the cocktail that came with the napkin), was instantly ridiculed as “voodoo economics.” Here’s the difficulty: To halve taxes but still collect the same total dollars, the economy would have to essentially double. That outcome was plausible only over the long, long term—to achieve a doubling in the economy would require a tax-driven increase in the real growth rate of 5 percent over its base rate, and it would still take fifteen years—and in the meantime deficits would abound.

As we’ve seen, a combination like this had never been tried before, and many of the constituent parts had not worked very well in isolation. Low investment led to low growth, lighter taxes and less progressiveness led to greater inequality, fiscal indiscipline produced debt and could produce inflation unless growth overall was slower, and so on. The only unambiguous benefit would be a near-term increase in consumption. Therefore, the program required an electorate that cherished consumption above all, was willing to overlook long-term consequences in favor of short-term gain, had no compunctions about stripping benefits from the most vulnerable, and could tolerate the magical thinking of the Laffer Curve while discounting the large body of evidence counseling against these strategies. As it happened, just such an electorate was at hand.

CHAPTER EIGHT

TAXES

Average federal tax rates in 2013 for households in all but the
top income quintile were significantly below the average rates
over the 1979–2013 period… Over that period, the average
individual income tax rate peaked at 11.9 percent in 1981,
declined [and then varied] in 2008 and 2009 to a low of 7.2
percent, as a result of declines in income and changes in tax law.

—Congressional Budget Office (2016)1

In general, the art of government consists in taking as much
money as possible from one class of citizens to give to the other.

—Voltaire (1764)

Etymology always has something to reveal, even about itself: It comes from the Greek etumos, the word for truth. In the case of “economics,” its origins are also Greek, also illuminating: It derives from οiϰονομιϰός, a term that originally referred to the management of the household. Economics was first applied to the administration of national households in the seventeenth century as “political economy.”2 That older term was vastly more apt than the adjectiveless, modern “economics,” because all economics are political economics: the shuffling of money according to the preferences of those in charge. No shuffling is more political and more economic than taxes—and no group more powerful over the past decades than the Boomers.

So it should be no surprise that a prime theme in the Boomers’ sociopathic ascendancy has been the consistent manipulation of taxes to serve generational ends. There were two major mechanisms by which Boomer enrichment (and national impoverishment) was achieved. The first was straightforward, a general lowering of tax rates that coincided with both the Boomers’ ascent to political power and the beginning of their prime earning years. The second mechanism required constantly adjusting specific tax policies to favor the interests of Boomers as they moved through their financial life cycles, lowering income taxes during periods where Boomers labored for wages, reducing capital gains taxes as Boomers became stockholders, and limiting and even briefly abolishing estate taxes when Boomers expected to inherit. However, taxes did not always move downward. When Boomers perceived tax hikes to be in their interests, some rates (like Social Security and Medicare taxes) were allowed to rise, though only enough to benefit Boomers, many of whom can expect to retrieve more from the system than they put in, before the system falls apart as the Boomers die off.*

Indeed, if you were to construct a wish list of tax policy (aside from no taxes, a situation that even the Tea Party reluctantly acknowledges is unfeasible), the best possible one for Boomer sociopaths would produce tax policies that mirrored Boomers’ progressions through their life cycles—a menu that looks like Appendix B and whose most salient parts are covered in this chapter. The sociopathic tax wishlist corresponds rather tightly with how policy actually developed. The consistency in the beneficiaries of these policies, enacted by both political parties regardless of economic climate (in booms, busts, and everything in between) demonstrates both the true power of the Boomers and their sociopathic lack of foresight and empathy.

The sociopathic appeal of generally lower taxes to the consumption-oriented Boomers is self-evident. The sociopathic consequences are made clear by the reallocation of financial burdens to everyone else: other payers of present-day taxes and future payers in the form of debt, piled up after decades of unrestrained spending not accompanied by corresponding tax collections. The system we have is the system the sociopaths wanted.

A Brief History of Income Taxation

Taxes occupy a strange position in the emotional landscape, oscillating between moments of great passion (April 15 and election days) and near-lethal boredom (every other day), and this is what makes fiddling with taxes so enticing: Politicians can always whip the electorate into a lather, winning a mandate for change, but rely on dullness and complexity to obscure the true consequences of tax adjustments. All that matters is making sure that a plurality of voters understand that they will be beneficiaries of favorable treatment (even if not the primary beneficiaries), without focusing overmuch on what the consequences will be and what others will bear them. That plurality of voters has, for many decades, been the Boomers.

To the extent it’s necessary to prove taxes are boring and difficult, one need only point to the fact that most Americans pay someone else to do theirs.3 As for passion, there is the evidence of history. Disputes over taxes have erupted into disorder and often violence many times, including the event that notionally led to our nation’s founding, the Boston Tea Party, whose name has been appropriated by contemporary antitaxers.

The physical violence has subsided; the anger has not. Instead, tax fury broadened to encompass the idea that all taxes are effectively consumption taxes, and for the sociopath, thievery, rather than a social tithe. So yesterday’s handful of moonshiners wielding pitchforks in the Whiskey Rebellion (1791–1794) have been supplanted today by entire Boomer governments grinding to a halt over money disputes (1995 onward) before reaching a sociopathically palatable outcome. All three full peacetime government shutdowns in American history happened during Boomer Congressional control, and each featured taxes and related budgetary matters as main events.

The primary source of dispute today is income tax, and Boomer politicians find there is always plenty to be angry about. Flip open the twenty-plus volumes of federal tax law and pick a line—injustice will be found wherever the fat finger of the Boomer Congressman from Middle Nowhere, animated by the Holy Ghost of the AARP, happens to land. At least as to income taxes, it was not always thus, for the simple reason that for a long time there was nothing like a modern federal income tax. This tax-free Eden remains relevant, because it is to this prelapsarian condition that Grover Norquist and his highly influential Americans for Tax Reform wish to return. Let’s be clear: This is not an overstatement. Norquist (b. 1956, prime Boomer) has opined that the America he wants to re-create is the one that existed right “up until Teddy Roosevelt, when the socialists took over….[and imposed] the income tax, the death tax, regulation, all that.”4 “Regulation, all that,” of course, means everything we understand to be the modern state; it is, per Norquist, anathema.

Norquist—an executive director of the College Republicans until 1983—emerged as a national figure during the Republican campaigns of the 1980s and has been a force ever since. In 1986, Norquist prepared “The Pledge,” a pseudocontract between candidates/officeholders and the electorate, that required its signers to “oppose any and all” personal and corporate tax increases, whether these hikes were accomplished directly or through the elimination of deductions; candidates signed on in droves.5 In the 1990s, Boomers Norquist and Gingrich coauthored the Contract with America, another tax-hostile agreement between electorate and GOP representatives (and again, at odds with the notionally elitist concept of representative democracy). In the 2000s, Norquist allied closely with Bush II, who pushed tax cuts further than Reagan. In the present antitax era, Norquist is a sort of anti–St. Jude, a patron saint of winning causes. (Trump has also prepared his own anti-tax “Contract.”)

Before 1913—when “the socialists took over”—income taxes were unconstitutional. The federal government had occasionally experimented with them, including during the Civil War, during which other Constitutional niceties like habeas corpus had also been suspended, but the Supreme Court put its foot down in Pollock v. Farmer’s Loan & Trust Co. (1895). As originally written, the Constitution required that all “direct taxes” be “apportioned among the several States which may be included within this Union, according to their respective numbers.”6 The government couldn’t tax based on amounts of income, just on amounts of people; in other words, per capita taxes, the simplest, most regressive form of tax possible (watchers of Fox News may now be seeing the currency of this digression). Pre-1913, if the federal government needed revenue, the Constitution allowed customs, duties, and excise taxes, which are a mixed blessing, since they operate as consumption taxes (generally good) but restrain free trade (so-so then, bad now).

Ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment in 1913 allowed for modern income taxation. Taxes started low and then rose substantially over the next thirty years. After World War II, the highest maximum rates reached 70–91 percent. Were Hillary Clinton to have proposed anything like this level of taxation—levels that prevailed under ur-Republicans Eisenhower and Nixon (both implicitly branded by Norquist as “socialists”)—the DNC would have been the first to rummage up any willing remnants of the Bush dynasty to replace her. The point of this context is not to demand a return to the era of 90 percent taxation, but simply to remind that in the context of present debates, rates of taxation are relatively low in nominal and other terms. Indeed, taxes are too low overall, insufficient to keep the government fully functioning or make essential investments for growth, at least not without major revisions to entitlement programs of which Boomers are and will continue to be the chief beneficiaries.*

It is said the Devil can quote scripture to his own purpose; as the core federal tax code is approximately three times longer than the King James Bible, the various Satans of Taxation (pick your ideological Lucifer: Paul Krugman, Thomas Piketty, or the opinionators of the Wall Street Journal and its parent, News Corporation, etc.) never lack for material. Between the 5,248 pages of the Internal Revenue Code, the additional 68,606 pages of “related materials,” the tens of thousands of interpretive releases, legal precedents, and so on—all prolix and incomprehensible and amended almost continuously—it seems the only thing one can truly know about taxes is that one’s own share is too high.7

So how to sort through this thicket, to find some reasonable way to understand how taxes have evolved over the past several decades? There are three basic lenses: (1) nominal rates (i.e., official tax rates); (2) average rates (i.e., the percentage of income actually paid, after accounting for deductions, adjustments, giveaways, etc.); and, (3) total tax paid across the entire tax base (i.e., the government’s real take). Alone, each tells a different story. Quoting selectively, both the RNC and DNC can easily find ways to testify that taxes are radically high or dangerously low. Only comparing the three different metrics shows the full picture, a landscape perverted by giveaways to Boomer political power. What they reveal, as we will see, is that nominal rates have been in steep decline, effective rates have been mixed among income groups (tending to favor the middle-class and persons now old), and total taxes have not declined very much as a fraction of the economy—and in combination, that means the history of Boomer tax policy is not so much a history of tax reduction as tax reallocation.

The First Tax Revolts

No generation has been quite so convinced of I’m-paying-too-much than the Boomers, though of course, their dependence on magical thinking and moody hatred of rational argument, combined with the sheer complexity of the tax code, makes it difficult to engage with them on the subject. Nevertheless, the data are what they are and the sheer unsubtlety of Boomerism makes it easy enough to see what is happening—as Boomers became more powerful, their taxes declined.

As with so many things, the beginning of the Boomer tax revolt had its origins in the Vietnam War. For the Boomers not only did not want to serve in the war (naturally, for moral reasons), they did not wish to pay for it, either (also, naturally, for moral reasons). Expanding on the protest we encountered in Chapter 3, a group of 448 writers and editors, including leading Boomer student organizer Todd Gitlin (b. 1943), took out a full-page ad in 1968, saying the signers would refuse to pay a proposed 10 percent federal war surcharge because it would be used to fund a conflict of which they disapproved; in an act of freelance accounting, about a third refused to pay an additional 23 percent of their income tax, which they also thought would fund the war.8 (The word used in the solicitation for signatures was “pledge,” which must amuse Norquist.9) The New York Times, the Washington Post, the Chicago Tribune, the Boston Globe, and others refused to take the ad, the Times on the grounds that the ad called for illegal activity (it did), but then as now, the New York Post held itself to a different standard and ran it.* But as we all know, taxes are complicated, so just to be safe, singer and antiwar protestor Joan Baez withheld 60 percent of her bill.10 The explicit inspiration for this little tax rebellion was Henry David Thoreau (quoted in the ad itself), the mystic narcissist and icon of Boomer antirationalism who materialized in Chapter 5. Thoreau said he refused to pay taxes as a protest of the Mexican-American War and slavery, but his Walden jailing actually resulted from failure to pay a local poll tax that had little to do with either war or slaves.11 Not even the president gets a line-item budget veto, but these Walden-inflected groups proposed to give it to themselves. Society cannot work like that.

No Taxation, with Representation

The arrival of real political power rendered informal protests unnecessary, and Boomers quickly began rewriting the tax code, starting with marginal rates. Marginal rates resemble “suggested retail prices” in that they are the official rates that no one actually pays; yet when the public thinks about taxes, it’s marginal rates that transfix. Most of these rates, especially on the last and highest dollars of income, have been in steep decline for some time, a process originally motivated by some good intentions and with some economic justification. Over time, tax cuts became unmoored from their worthy foundations, pushed along by pure sentiment. The net effect was destructive and enduring, because marginal rates are sticky: Once they go down, it is hard to make them go back up.

For context, the highest marginal rates during and after World War II ranged from 91 to 94 percent, and the tax code was incredibly complicated besides, with a profusion of brackets, thirty-three different ones by 1974.12 In the 1970s, the complexity of the tax code became worse as inflation drove “bracket creep.” Because the various brackets were not linked to inflation, increases in nominal wages drove payers into higher brackets that themselves remained fixed, even though workers’ real wages might not have increased at all. As a result, people could end up paying a greater percentage of their income despite no real change in the amount they made. These were problems that required redress, but like many revolutions, the tax revolt ran far beyond its original justifications.

Led by President Reagan in the White House, Representative Jack Kemp in the House, and William Roth in the Senate (who later gave his name to the Roth IRA), Congress reformed taxes in 1981. Over several years, the law would lower marginal rates (the top rate would go from 70 percent to 50 percent, e.g.) and index brackets to inflation, eliminating creep. The net effect of the Reagan revisions were that all Americans except the poorest 20 percent would pay less in taxes. Tax cutters argued society as a whole would gain as benefits “trickled down,” though when it became clear the flow would really be a trickle, not a flood, the justification was quietly dropped even as the policy (and the deficits it spurred) continued. This was sociopathically irrelevant, of course, because the prime objective of lower taxes was achieved.

Although the tax system clearly needed reform, bad changes were tucked in along with the good, with predictable beneficiaries. The 1981 act not only lowered taxes overall, it had specific generational consequences. Some mechanisms were explicit. Inheritances below $175,625 had been previously excluded from taxation; the exclusion would increase to $600,000 in 1987, more than tripling the tax-free inheritance amount.13 The chief beneficiaries would be, of course, the Boomers—and the reason the estate tax cut could be safely delayed until 1987 (unlike reductions to the income tax, which had to be immediate) was that the Boomers’ parents still had a few years left in them. The second mechanism improved tax-free retirement savings, and again, this was of greatest benefit to workers furthest from retirement age, i.e., the Boomers.

Contrary to popular myth, Reagan not only cut taxes, but raised them, and this laid bare the struggle between new Boomer preferences and the older culture of fiscal responsibility, a battle that would eventually and decisively be resolved in favor of the Boomers. The 1981 cuts spawned deficits vastly larger than predicted. So Congress, still populated by more responsible generations, modified the earlier cuts, slowing their adoption and tinkering with some technical details, and the Gipper assented. The largest tax cut in American history was therefore almost immediately followed by one of the largest increases. The net effect of the two programs was still a significant cut; not exactly a triumph of probity, but indicative of a (fading) sense of responsibility. However, Boomers would soon be thrown another bone. In 1984, to help offset deficits, Social Security benefits for higher earners were taxed for the first time.*,14 Of course, even the oldest Boomers were twenty years away from collecting benefits and that distance, coupled with the possibility of later repeal, limited Boomer objections.

Marginal Tax Rates: The Price No One Pays

What’s going on here? These are the highest and lowest marginal tax rates—and while politicians fixate on them, these are not the tax rates anyone actually pays, thanks to deductions, credits, lower marginal rates on the first units of income, etc. As a general matter, marginal rates were notably low in the Boomer years.15

During the 1980s, Congress also raised payroll taxes—the only taxes to experience sustained increases during the Boomer ascendancy—to keep Social Security and Medicare solvent through Boomer retirements. The immediate costs would be borne by the Boomers and their children, but the Boomers could accept this because the Boomers expected to recoup everything they paid and possibly more. That employers usually bore half of payroll taxes also helped; the Boomers were not yet significant owners of capital, and not all of the effect would flow into changed incomes. The revision of payroll taxes could therefore be viewed as something of a generational win.

In 1986, the tax system was overhauled again, inevitably in ways favorable to the Boomers. The number of brackets collapsed from fourteen to two by 1988, with the lowest set at 14 percent and the highest at 28 percent (down from 50 percent). The limits for tax-advantaged 401(k)s were lowered from $30,000 per year (which had benefitted older, wealthier workers at cost to the Boomers) to $7,000, which was more in line with what younger Boomer professionals could actually save. Capital gains lost preferential treatment, and the maximum rate therefore rose to 28 percent (from 20 percent), but the median Boomer was only mid-thirties, had neither a large stock portfolio nor plans to mass-liquidate anytime soon, and therefore (like employer payroll taxes) the burden fell on the old and the rich, whose ranks the Boomers had not yet joined. So Ronald Reagan, the fabled tax crusader, not only increased taxes, but did so several times—just in very targeted ways that happened to coincide with the needs of the Boomers, who were then an enormous fraction of the electorate.

The one area where the 1986 reform appeared bad for Boomers was the elimination of deductibility of personal-interest payments of any kind—a potential constraint on the consumption the sociopathic Boomers cherished. The more than compensatory sweetener was that mortgage interest would remain deductible, now for up to $1 million in indebtedness, and another $100,000 in “unrelated interest”—and thus, the home equity line of credit was born.* A little paperwork, and the Boomers once again had their personal interest deduction, and indeed, “much of the [new, mortgage] debt finance[ed] vacations, cars, boats, and other consumer purchases.”16 Of course, this was the part of the Boomers’ life cycle in which they were snapping up real estate at tremendous volume, and while the numerical bulk of the deduction went to the richest (as is the case with most deductions), the most populous beneficiary group was the most-indebted (i.e., youngest) homeowners, whose ranks were swelling with Boomer voters. The reforms of the 1980s did not help as much as taxpayers thought they would, but they definitely adjusted the burden downward and in many cases away from the Boomers, or toward programs from which the Boomers (but not their children) could reasonably expect to fully collect.

Overall, the tax reforms of the 1980s had many benefits—nominal taxes were too high, bracket creep was a real problem, the tax base had been too narrow (i.e., too many loopholes and exclusions), and there were too many brackets and other complexities—but these sowed in the fertile field of the Boomer mind a poisonous seed. And the seed was this: The only appropriate direction for taxes was downward, at least for taxes applicable to the Boomers.

The 1990s—Read Their Lips: No New Taxes

The effect of Boomer tax obsession could be seen in the early 1990s, when two very different politicians raised taxes very slightly, and were punished accordingly. Politician One was George Bush the First, who instructed Congress: “Read my lips: No new taxes.” Of course, no such effort was necessary because: (1) Bush spoke the words audibly and (2) he raised taxes. Bush’s overall increase was small, with the highest earners bearing 40 percent of the rise directly; another 40 percent of the hike came from increased excise taxes.17 The reform was responsible, modest, and fell most heavily on a core Bush constituency (the rich) who could be counted on to suffer the indignity and reelect their candidate. Instead, Bush was fired, which was a remarkable outcome. Bush I had just presided over the successful Gulf War I, earning some of the highest approval ratings in history. Though the economy had slowed modestly, the 1990–1991 recession was historically mild, brief, and nothing compared to the crises that followed. True, Bush broke his word, but that alone was unremarkable. Presidents violate promises all the time, and few for reasons as good: Bush sincerely believed that changed facts commanded changed tax policy, and the tariffs that fell heavily on his base. Empirical, responsible, self-sacrificing—another electorate might have found Bush’s tax policy commendable. The problem was that Bush violated his word on taxes, and for Boomers that elevated the sin from venal to mortal.

Thus, a minor increase in taxes helped pave the way for the first Boomer president, William Jefferson Clinton. Clinton accused Bush of being untrustworthy(!) and campaigned for tax relief for “middle-class Americans” and “families with children,” two groups with which the Boomers correctly self-identified.18 (At this point, median Boomers were forty, had children, and like all Americans rich, poor, and otherwise, viewed themselves as “middle-class” and thus potential recipients of Clintonian largesse.) Bill Clinton also promised to “force the rich to pay their fair share.”19 Let us leave aside, as Clinton did, that this was just what Bush had started to do.

Clinton duly won and then proceeded to repeat Bush’s mistake. Clinton is lionized by certain Leftish op-ed pages for raising taxes in 1993, and he did, but that was not exactly what he promised, or what many voters expected him, to do. Indeed, of the roughly 25 percent of voters who thought the violation of Bush’s “read my lips” pledge was “very important” in their presidential vote, two-thirds voted for Clinton—and one conclusion, in combination with Clinton’s rhetoric about middle-class relief, is that these and other voters expected Clinton to cut their taxes.20 Instead, Clinton raised taxes, mainly but not exclusively on the rich.21 It squeaked out of the House 218–216 (more than forty Democrats voted against it) and escaped a Democratic Senate only because Al Gore cast a tie-breaking vote—i.e., opposition to Clinton’s 1993 increase was partly bipartisan.22

Clinton’s was not a blockbuster hike, and it certainly helped that it targeted the rich, among whose ranks necessarily few, still-youngish Boomers, or anyone else, dwelled. (It’s called the 1 percent for a reason.) Still, the tax package passed only by Gore’s single, fortuitous vote; even the Democrats went berserk, and Clinton found himself apologizing to his own base for daring to raise taxes, however modestly.23 This aftermath helps show that what people thought they were buying in 1992 was a tax cutter, not a tax hiker.

Thus, another modest tax revision allowed the second great Boomer politician to emerge, Newt Gingrich. The commonalities between the two sociopathic Boomer chieftains is striking—age, philandering, murky financial dealings, ethics violations, tax avoidance, dramatic censures (the second impeachment of a president, in Clinton’s case; the first official reprimand of a Speaker of the House, in Gingrich’s), a premature graying of hair entirely understandable in light of the foregoing—really, they could have been the best of friends. And they even agreed over time, sort of, on the need for tax reduction.

This time, no political mistakes would be made, no new charges to the rich or sensible supplements to payroll taxes, absolutely nothing that could be misconstrued by the tax-obsessed Boomers. Benefits would be made perfectly clear to the voters who mattered. The Boomers, then middle-aged, had all sorts of middle-aged issues, including school-age children, decrepit parents, homes to trade up, stock portfolios to maximize, and retirements to plan. All of these were duly and expressly catered to: a child credit of $400 appeared (rising to $500 in 1999); the estate tax exemption would increase from $600,000 to $1 million by 2006, and all assets would be “stepped up” at the parents’ death, meaning that all unrealized capital gains accrued during the parents’ lifetime could be tax free at death (i.e., Boomer inheritances instantly became much more valuable); gains on sale of homes up to $500,000 were exempted from tax; and the two capital gains tax brackets were lowered, from 28 percent to 20 percent and 15 percent to 10 percent.24 An added bonus was the creation of Roth IRAs, which were functionally useless to older generations then retiring, but of great use to middle-aged Boomers, as were the various education credits established, the better to subsidize the schooling of the Boomers’ children.25

Doctrinally, the Clinton cuts were somewhat confusing: economically unorthodox and contrary to commonly understood Democratic policy. In 1997, the economy was growing and it was by no means clear that a tax cut was required; could it not, perhaps, stoke some sort of speculative bubble in the assets favored by the tax bill, like stocks or houses? And had not Democrat Clinton, after all, promised to soak the rich during his first campaign? The answers were obviously all some form of “yes.” Then again, Clinton and his counterparts in Congress were Boomers and beholden to their cogenerationalists. Tax cuts emerged from the legislature with strong bipartisan support and Clinton signed.

The 2000s—Lather, Rinse, Repeat

Fast-forward past the Monica Lewinsky scandal, which effectively ended the Clinton presidency, to Bush II. The situation had changed dramatically: the dot-com crash, 9/11, and a major recession. The prescription, however, remained the same: more Boomer-friendly tax cuts. Essentially all tax rates were slashed by about 10 percent, with Boomers doing by far the best. In their peak earning years and with retirement fast approaching, it was essential to lower income taxes and to cut capital gains taxes to fertilize stock portfolios that would soon be harvested. To better appeal to Boomers, tax-advantaged retirement accounts were modified so that people over 50 (at the time, the Boomers were between 37 and 61, with the median Boomer a predictable 49) could make excess tax-free contributions. And needless to say, with the Boomers’ parents having one foot in the grave and the other on a banana peel, it had become essential to modify the estate tax. The estate tax exemption quickly rose from $675,000 in 2001 to $2,000,000 in 2006, then to $3,500,000 in 2009 and was finally to be abolished altogether in 2010, a period corresponding with the actuarially forecasted demise of the median Boomers’ parents.26

There was some sense in cutting taxes during a recession, but how the taxes were cut was illuminating—from a Keynesian perspective, the best cuts would be the cuts that led to the fastest spending, not the fastest squirreling away of retirement funds by older Americans. Theory was, of course, meaningless to the nonempirical Boomers. The political bargain was that many cuts would sunset in 2010, but by 2010, the median Boomer would be fifty-eight, aging out of the income-earning years, and nearing eligibility for Social Security. Tax cuts might sunset, but it would be a sunset the Boomers could ride into.

So what happened to the Bush II cuts? They were followed in 2003 by legislation that accelerated certain portions of the 2001 cuts and further reduced taxes on qualified gains.27 Even the election, in 2008, of Bush’s ideological opposite didn’t change the general trajectory. In 2010, under the leadership of a now Democratic Congress and Executive, almost all Bush II’s tax cuts were extended; it was “change you could believe in,” if you believed the Boomers were still in control, which they were. Inheritance taxes reappeared, but at a lower rate than before the Bush II cuts (40 percent vs. 55 percent) and with a much higher exemption ($5 million versus $675,000 in 2001), which covered essentially all Boomers still in a position to inherit, since few estates exceeded the exemption.28 Certain payroll taxes also rolled back for a bit, but the reduction was temporary and small, and while not helpful to the long-term solvency of Social Security, would have little impact on the Boomers themselves.29 It was a giveaway, and it passed.

There was some justification during the recession’s nadir to avoid a tax hike, though that logic had little application to items like lowered estate taxes—then again, logic was not in command. Predictably, even after the recession ended(ish), the Bush tax cuts were essentially made permanent by President Obama in 2013, with the exception of a modest reversion in top rates, from 35 percent to 39.6 percent, for the wealthiest taxpayers (e.g., couples making more than $450,000 a year). FICA (payroll) cuts were also reversed.30 Maximum capital gains rates were restored to 20 percent, but here’s the thing—dividend rates, scheduled to return to 39.6 percent, were kept to a maximum 20 percent.*,31 Because retirees favor dividend stocks (like utilities), which are perceived as safer and provide current income, the capital gains twist was a direct giveaway to the dividend-collecting classes—i.e., the rich and the old. Even more important, the capital gains tax did not increase for the cherished middle class.32 As for estate taxes, they had become even more urgent. By 2013, the median Boomer was already sixty-one, and those Boomers’ parents who were still living would not remain so for much longer. The already generous $5 million exemption was therefore indexed to inflation to preserve its value.33 The 2000s, therefore, might have been no more than a tactical success for lower taxes overall, but they were a decisive victory for Boomers.

The Rest of the Goodie Bag

There were two other disguised tax giveaways to the Boomers from the 1970s to the 2010s: property taxes and corporate taxes. Both can be covered briefly. Property taxes before the 1970s had been a mess, riddled with loopholes and anachronisms from the age of farms, land grants, and low inflation. During the 1970s, before the Boomers were fully in control, there had been a number of property tax revolts in several states, most prominently in California. Inflation had driven the assessed values of properties up, and since taxes were based on nominal values, taxes went up faster than any corresponding change in real value. So California voters limited taxes to 1 percent of assessed value and capped the rate of assessment increases.34 Instead of indexing to reality, California set the maximum rate of appreciation at an arbitrary 2 percent per year. General inflation, of course, was much higher then and the appreciation of California property higher than inflation overall for much of the next forty years. The immediate effect was mild, because California had a larger-than-average government that could be productively trimmed and a budget surplus that cushioned the impact on localities collecting property tax. (The state surplus was $5 billion in 1978 dollars when the proposition was passed, or about $18 billion in present dollars versus large annual deficits in the recent past, reaching negative $20 billion in 2011–2012 before achieving rough balance in 2014.35) For a time, property tax limits were not a major problem and, had they been as temporary as the inflation that prompted them, even appropriate to the unusual conditions of the late 1970s.

After inflation had been vanquished by 1982, it became clear that the caps had become less shield than subsidy. By this point, Boomers were homeowners and therefore the beneficiaries of the property tax caps whose calculations grew more unrealistic (and thus more valuable) every year. Given that the Boomers were increasingly in control, they would never give up this cherished perk, forcing budget shortfalls disproportionately onto the shoulders of nonhomeowners—i.e., the young and the poor—in the form of regressive higher sales taxes and the like—anything, that is, but taxes on Boomer homes. The effect was a transfer to Boomers, at the cost of younger people whose rates of home ownership were depressed and who enjoyed less benefit from the housing tax shield.

The second major change, to corporate income taxes, also had substantial benefit to the Boomers, albeit indirectly. Effective corporate taxes rose briefly and sharply from 1979 to 1987 and then fell substantially. And even though the United States still has some of the highest official corporate taxes in the developed world and these rates have remained largely unchanged since the mid-1980s, the effective rates of corporate taxation fell somewhat, and for some large companies all the way to zero. Although effective rates overall are not wildly different from other advanced economies, there is now an increasing divergence between corporate profits’ share of the economy and the share represented by the taxes on those profits.* The figure on the next page illustrates the trend.

The beneficiaries, of course, were people who owned shares in the companies paying lower taxes. In 1979, the Boomers were too young to hold many stocks, so their huge voting power tilted not so much pro or con as indifferent. As the Boomers joined the stock-owning classes in the mid-1980s, when most were in their thirties and forties, effective corporate taxes began to decline. Higher after-tax profits could then be realized in higher stock prices, higher dividend payments, or both. The only thing necessary for Boomers to maximize those gains were decreases to capital gains and dividend taxes, obediently delivered in 1987 and 1997, by Ronald Reagan and Bill Clinton, and preserved by Bush II and Obama—four radically different politicians, though all with the same critical constituency: Boomers. Most of the gains accrued to the wealthiest, but everyone in the stock-holding classes, including the Boomers, benefited at the expense of the rest.* This was especially the case for middle-income Boomers, who held their stocks in tax-advantaged accounts. The income/contribution limits of such accounts means that it’s the Boomer middle class that’s avoiding and/or postponing capital gains taxes to a relatively greater extent than the workaday rich (whose additional wealth is sufficient to place it outside tax-advantaged retirement plans but is insufficient to justify the expense of bespoke tax shelters).

Corporations: Something to Contribute

What’s going on here? Corporate profits have been rising as a share of the total economy for some time, but corporate taxes have been falling then flattening on the same measure. There is therefore at least some room for convergence and additional revenue (accompanied by meaningful reform of the vast loopholes that allow some large corporations to get away with very low tax bills).36

Finally, to the extent explicit tax decreases did not satisfy, the defunding of the IRS and concurrent reduction in the likelihood of audits, especially for middle-income payers, authorized less scrupulous taxpayers to adjust their payments to more desirable levels. Just between 2010 and 2015–2016, enforcement personnel at the IRS declined by 23 percent; by the end individual audits hit an eleven-year low, and new IRS appropriations from Congress were directed away from enforcement.37 Even though the IRS trumpeted the hiring of seven hundred new enforcement workers in 2016, it would end that fiscal year with two thousand fewer staff than at that year’s beginning.38 Hobbling the IRS was like posting a speed limit and then removing all the cops and cameras; for sociopaths, it was a green light for fraud. The annual “tax gap”—the difference between what the IRS believes is owed and what is actually and timely paid—ran over $400 billion dollars annually for the 2008–2010 period, the most recent years analyzed by the Service, and that was before recent cuts to enforcement.39 It will hardly be surprising if the tax gap widens.

Taxation and Consequences

Let us remember that the basic purpose of any tax
cut program in today’s environment is to reduce the
momentum of expenditure growth by restraining
the amount of revenues available and trust that
there is a political limit to deficit spending.

—Alan Greenspan (1979)40

Hogcock, which is a combination of hogwash and poppycock.

—Jack Donaghy, 30 Rock

Notwithstanding all these tax cuts, the government has not simply evaporated or been cut in half, although that was the stated intent of the 1980s tax revolution. Returning to Grover Norquist, the purpose of the tax revolt was to starve the government of revenue so that it would shrink back to its size around the turn of the last century, making government small enough “to drown it in a bathtub.”41 (The government is not a person, but metaphorical murder of an institution that embodies society does reek of sociopathy.) The reason Norquist has succeeded in lowering tax rates but not abolishing the government is that people like the benefits each provides and will not part with either.

This presents a certain mystery about mechanisms—if taxes fell, how could government soldier on? Partly, the government borrowed heavily; we’ll take that up in Chapter 9. Secondly, while nominal tax rates have gone down, taxes’ total share of GDP remained fairly stable, aside from brief gyrations during the first dot-com bubble and during the Great Recession. That overall stability, against a background of constant changes to the code, implies a reshuffling of tax burdens.

The first and most important aspect of reshuffling was the rising share paid by the rich, who paid a large and increasing share of taxes through 2000, had a respite, and saw their rates rise after 2012. Given all the heated rhetoric about the rich, that might come as a surprise, but the electoral math more or less guaranteed that would be the case. For some time, the real story of declining taxation played out in the bottom 80 percent of taxpayers (aka, the mythical “middle class”). Only in 2000 did tax burdens on the rich really decline, but then again, burdens fell for almost everyone else. Here’s what the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis had to say in 2010: “Before 2000, the tax burden shifted from the lowest 80 percent of earners to the highest 20 percent; since 2000, the burden has shrunk for all groups, but more so for the highest earners.”42 Since 2013, the rich have experienced the sharpest increase in taxes.43

There are several ways to think about what happened, each presented in graphs on the following pages. The first is to consider how average federal tax rates have evolved since 1979. There has been a pronounced downward trend in tax burden on the middle class, especially relative to the rich and the poor, with taxes perking up slightly since 2013. The middle class got relative tax cuts throughout this period, a period that heavily overlapped with the Boomers’ prime working years.

The second way to think about taxes are “average” rates. Marginal rates apply to different chunks of income, starting with low rates on the first dollars of income and progressively rising to 39.6+ percent for dollars of income over $413,200. Average rates, by contrast, represent the fraction of total income actually paid, and are always lower than maximum marginal rates because even rich people pay very low marginal taxes on their first dollars of income. These average rates are quite low for most income groups and they can even be negative for the poorest Americans, who can receive more money from Washington than they pay in federal taxes. This leads to another way to think about taxes—the share of government revenue provided relative to a person’s share of income. It’s not quite “give versus get,” since rich people frequently consume more of society’s resources than poor people, though it has something of this dynamic. More precisely, most Americans pay less in federal taxes than they earn as a fraction of total income. This shouldn’t be surprising, since the point of a progressive system is to subsidize poorer Americans with higher taxes on the rich—what is surprising (or should be to middle-class Tea Partiers) is where the break-even point rests. Only the top 20 percent pays more in federal taxes than it earns as a share of income, showing just how shielded the middle class (and even upper middle class) has been under the Boomers. These dynamics appear in a later figure.

The Government’s Stable Share

What’s going on here? The government’s total take, as a fraction of GDP, has remained surprisingly constant over time, with some volatility after the mid-1990s as the economy coped with bubbles, panics, and some large tax cuts. However, the general stability of tax revenue strongly suggests that endless tax adjustments really just shifted burdens around. Because so much of government revenue after the 1980s is accounted for by levies for senior programs and distributed accordingly, and because those programs are not fully funded, the burden has been shifted away from the middle class and old and toward everyone else—i.e., away from the mainstream Boomers.44

So, wait—did taxes go up or down? For which groups? And with all those tax cuts, how did the government not collapse? There are several answers, some of which we’ve covered but are included again for convenience, since taxes are confusing, perhaps deliberately so. First, taxes on the rich generally increased until 2000, as a total and often as a percentage of income, subsided for a period, and then moved upward again after 2013. This offset falling taxes on middle-class Boomers. Second, the tax base widened somewhat; i.e., somewhat more people paid taxes. Third, the economy had some one-off spurts, as in the late 1990s (dot-com I) that lifted many payers into higher brackets temporarily.

It’s the fourth and fifth answers that are by far the most important, however, and these heavily involve the Boomers. Answer four is that tax burdens were reallocated substantially, away from the Boomers toward almost everyone else—i.e., the Boomers paid less, and everyone else paid more, and this accounts for both the relative stability of the tax take over time, and many of the fifteen thousand–plus changes to the code, some of which we have covered, like mortgage interest deductions and tax-advantaged retirement programs. The middle-class Boomers faced lower tax burdens during their prime earning years relative to the middle class of the 1940s–1970s and throughout, the middle class didn’t pay as much in federal taxes as it earned as a share of national income. The fifth and final answer has the same consequence as the fourth: The nation has not, with (no) due respect to Greenspan, responded to lower taxes with fiscal restraint. The government continues to spend at a fairly stable (and substantial) rate, and the resulting deficits have been financed with debt, whose burdens will be passed on to younger generations. Finally, the nature of spending changed: There was a shift from investment in items like R&D to consumption transfers like entitlements, the latter as useful to the Boomers as they are unsustainable, at least in their current configuration. It is to these manipulations we now turn, starting with debt.

Tax Cuts for the Middle Class

What’s going on here? This chart shows how average federal tax rates (what people really pay) have changed relative to the rate scheme in 1979. The story here is that middle class tax rates have been going down while taxes on wealthier Americans have varied. None of this should be surprising, since the stated goal of mainstream politicians is always some form of middle-class tax cut. This chart, by the way, does not say anything about the level of rates—just their relative direction over time.45

Who Pays What to Whom?

What’s going on here? The federal tax system is designed to be “progressive,” so that wealthier people pay a larger fraction of their income, which is redistributed to the rest of society—and that is what this chart shows. Only the top quintile pays more than its pro rata share (this is what the bars show). State and local taxes can be more regressive than federal levies and offset some of this dynamic, but what is striking is how dependent the United States is on its richest citizens. The lines, for the record, indicate the average actual tax rate paid by each group—and again, the shape of the line is no surprise (wealthier people pay higher rates), but the level may be a surprise, since average taxes are so much lower than the “rack rates” we saw in the marginal rates chart. Moreover, the graph suggests that many Americans may not be contributing as much as they think they do and that tax rates overall are not enormously high.46

CHAPTER ELEVEN

BOOMER FINANCE: THE VICIOUS CYCLE OF RISK AND DECEIT

They are frequently deceitful and manipulative in
order to gain personal profit or pleasure…
They may repeatedly lie… con others, or malinger…
They may display a glib, superficial charm and can be quite
verbally facile (e.g., using technical terms or jargon that
might impress someone who is unfamiliar with the topic).

—DSM-V1

I’m tired of Love: I’m still more tired of Rhyme.
But Money gives me pleasure all the time.

—Hilaire Belloc2

Given the Boomers’ legacy of mismanagement and misappropriation, how have we gone so long without some sort of counterrevolution? Part of the answer, as we saw in Chapter 7, is that the Boomers still have great raw political power and will for some time—and as to the entitlement budget, they have the support of their elders. Another significant explanation is that, in classic sociopathic fashion, the Boomers have engaged in a campaign of deceit, reaching into their wunderkammer of generational duplicity to offer consoling fictions to the population they govern. The mendacious assortment includes disingenuous financial dialogue essential to maintaining the expropriations necessary to fund the Boomers’ insatiable consumer appetites and stretches to oppressive political discourse designed to squelch debate (carefully packaged in the form of sensitivity to the various shibboleths of the Right and Left). In the event mere words fail to lull the electorate, the Boomers have resorted to outright oppressions made by the state’s monopolies on the money supply and violence, and whether the labels be “crisis management” or “law and order,” the oppressive effect is the same. When all other options have been exhausted, the Boomers simply ignore problems whose greatest effects will fall outside their lifetimes and are of correspondingly little concern.

All people lie, and the political class most of all, but the scope of Boomer deceptions goes far beyond the customary embellishment (e.g., the improbable tale peddled by Hillary Clinton, b. 1947, about being named after mountaineer Sir Edmund Hillary, who summited Everest in 1953 and was previously a beekeeper whose first major summit was in 1948, to say nothing of the misstatements emitted by her 2016 presidential opponent).3 Boomer lies are systemic, sociopathic, and an essential mechanism for both the destruction of wealth and the transfer of what remains from younger generations to the Boomers. The result is a socially dysfunctional but highly effective system of pacification founded on pathological misrepresentation, oppression, and sustained failures to act.

Nowhere are the dynamics of deception more pervasive, in government and the private sector, than in the financial arena. The Boomers’ reshaping of commerce combined an astonishing tolerance for risk with widespread dishonesty. Every time the system wobbled, the Boomers’ solution was more risk and more dishonesty. It would be convenient, perhaps even comforting, to dismiss financial impropriety under the Boomers as just the product of a few bad actors in a perpetually disreputable industry. The evidence does not fully admit such consolations. For decades after World War II, personal probity and a new regulatory framework produced a calmer and more honest system. With the exception of the Savings and Loan crisis (in which some Boomers participated), bubbles and scandals were comparatively few and small.

As the Boomers took greater control of both the public and private sectors, financial scandals grew to a scale never before seen and we now live in an era of permanent financial emergency. It was not just the work of isolated bankers or sloppy regulators. The transformation required the participation of all parts of Boomer society. Take, for example, the issuance of junk mortgages. These loans required consumers to apply for them, often without any reasonable belief they could be serviced; banks to underwrite them; investors to buy them after syndication; watchdogs to look away; auditors to sign off on incredible accounting; a legislature to gut restraining regulation; and a central bank, trapped in the middle, to engage in the expedient facilitation of all of the above. Subprime mortgages were just one part of a financial fractal where the same story repeated endlessly. In reality, the past few decades have not been so much a financial scandal as a social one, with the Boomers playing a leading role.

The Regulated Market: New Deal to Neoliberalism

Between the Depression and the Boomers’ neoliberal revolution, finance enjoyed a certain staid respectability. Scarred by the Depression, earlier generations tolerated less risk and deception than the Boomers would. These cultural traits were codified in, and reinforced by, a new regulatory system that demanded reasonable practices, adequate capital, periodic reporting, mandatory insurance to protect customers, and more. Entities like the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), and Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) enforced fairness and order. Both the public and private sectors were helped by the development of generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP) from 1939 to 1973, which allowed investors and regulators to better understand firms’ performance.4 These innovations favored truth over expedience, and objective fact over subjective projection, helping create a more stable financial system out of the chaos that came before.

Another helpful development, often overlooked, was the collection and publication of statistics. As future Justice Brandeis put it, “Publicity is justly commended as a remedy for social and industrial diseases. Sunlight is said to be the best of disinfectants.”5 The financial Lysol was provided by agencies created in the New Deal and reinforced in the 1970s by entities like the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) and the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). Data helped the market to discipline itself and regulators to make more informed judgments.*

Pre-Boomer governments, markets, and consumers demanded a more orderly system, and they largely succeeded in producing one. The system did not prevent occasional panics and financial failures, but securities frauds were limited in scope, bank failures few, and government intervention to save institutions largely unnecessary. Citizens could reasonably question whether finance, circa 1975, was insufficiently imaginative and somewhat overregulated without tossing overboard, as the Boomers would, essential parts of the system.

The revolutionary Boomer temperament, expressing itself though neoliberal doctrine, disdained incrementalism. Old practices were pushed aside, and as the predictable results manifested, the Boomers swept them under the rug through a wholesale campaign of financial deceit. It is not the mere fact that Boomers engaged in widespread financial deception that makes them sociopaths. In the rough-and-tumble 1870s, the Boomers’ practices would have been odious, though not completely deviant. By the 1970s, the case was different. Boomer financial culture operated contrary to prevailing mores while evading, watering down, and sometimes gutting the regulatory framework established by their parents. The result has been a scandalous samsara of fraud, abuse, and bailout.

Deceit and Deregulation

The degradation of words and numbers became an essential front in the war of deception. Linguistically, the revealing opprobrium of old-fashioned terms was dispatched; when old wine tasted rank, it was decanted into new and less judgmental bottles. Yesterday’s “borrowing” and “debt” became today’s “credit” and “leverage,” while “speculation” morphed into “investment” and “junk bonds” transitioned into “high-yield securities.” “Second mortgages,” a term synonymous with improvidence, were sanitized in the 1980s into “home equity lines of credit” and became a fixture of Boomer finances. In the event any of these bets succeeded, levies on gains could be avoided though “tax efficiency,” altogether more palatable than old-fashioned “tax evasion.”

The unsettling rise of debt and complexity on Wall Street required not just additions to the financial thesaurus, but entirely new entries in the dictionary of deceit. To pacify regulators after the dot-com crash, Wall Street assigned itself “compliance officers” and “risk managers.” Their chief purpose, as the financial collapse just a few years later made clear, was neither compliance nor risk mitigation, but the expansion of portfolios to the maximum extent possible under the least plausible conception of laws. To avoid detection, companies adopted “document retention policies” after the 1980s, whose chief effect was just the opposite: the disposal of inconvenient documents as soon as legally permissible. Arthur Andersen, for example, invoked its compliance with Enron’s document retention policy as a defense for elimination, via industrial shredder, of inconvenient evidence.6

Even before the books were shredded, they were cooked. An especially important innovation was off balance sheet (OBS) accounting. A conventional balance sheet is supposed to show all of an entity’s assets and liabilities, with the difference between them being the owners’ equity, a sort of net worth. The large and often disastrous liabilities Boomers accumulated tainted traditional balance sheets.* OBS accounting opened a wormhole into an alternative financial universe into which these problems could be dispatched. The term “off balance sheet” did not really exist before 1968 or so, and didn’t take off until the 1980s, before enjoying a truly spectacular heyday during the most recent financial fiascoes. The accounting profession adopted newly accommodating standards during the 1990s and 2000s that made OBS accounting particularly attractive. Obviously, one should always be suspicious of a parallel set of books, traditionally the friends of tax cheats and embezzlers. However, the Boomers’ affinity with deceit, irony, and magical thinking not only permitted the creation of this financial multiverse, but deemed it an invention worthy of praise.*

As we saw in Chapter 7, the government itself has enormous OBS liabilities, especially relating to entitlements; here’s how it accounts for them. Instead of presenting these items on the main balance sheet, the government deposits them in a footnote. For fiscal 2015, the main balance sheet shows $3.2 trillion in assets (of which almost $1 trillion are student loans) offset against $13.2 trillion in public debt, $6.7 trillion in pensions and benefits for federal employees including veterans, and another $1.6 trillion in “other”—for a total negative “net position” of $18.2 trillion.7 However, here of the government’s financial report consist of two notes to the financial statements, which reveal some $41.5 trillion in unfunded additional liabilities relating to entitlements, which themselves contain various notes and external references of their own, a recursive prolixity that would have stopped David Foster Wallace in his tracks.8 So, the government has a financial net worth of something between negative $18 and negative $60 trillion. The government doesn’t exactly hide the problems so much as reclassify them, for the simple reason that Washington would be in breach of major budgeting rules, like the debt ceiling, if it did not brush them under the rug of OBS and other types of accounting. (This is an example of where the “my problem” versus “not my problem” view of OBS accounting is useful—entitlements are “not my problem” for the Boomers because they won’t be paying for them.)

The government also does not have the firmest of grips on its liabilities. Partly, a certain haziness about the figures just comes from the understandable difficulties in accounting for the largest, most complicated entity in the world, especially over a multidecade time frame. Partly, however, the government has not established adequate procedures for self-comprehension. Like corporate financial statements, government books are subject to audit, and those audits come with an opinion about the fairness, integrity, and reasonableness of the books themselves. The comptroller general’s audit opinion of the government’s fiscal 2015 books does not encourage, as it notes “certain material weaknesses in internal control over financial reporting,” including of the $41 trillion in Social Security and Medicare entitlements in the notes, an “ineffective process” for preparing the entire set of financial statements, and the “federal government’s inability to account for and reconcile intragovernmental activities and balances,” which presumably includes the critical intragovernmental liability of the entitlements trust funds we saw in Chapter 8.9 These failings “hinder the federal government from having reliable financial information to operate in an efficient and effective manner.”10 The comptroller says that controls have gotten better since 1996—this has been a long-standing problem—but the considerable weaknesses that remain affect by far the majority of the government’s liabilities. Any improvement is small consolation: If you were a General Electric shareholder and the auditors said GE’s accounting department was out of its depth but slightly less so than before, GE would not be a stock you’d want to hold.

Government accountants are at least trying to be straightforward about OBS and other accounting. The private sector quickly discovered that for those of less noble mien, OBS was a financial septic tank. Nominally an energy firm, Enron was in reality a financial engineering company whose three most senior and culpable leaders were eventually convicted of fraud (all were Boomers), whose parallel sets of books, OBS accounts, and subsidiaries digested any financial inconveniences. Fortune named Enron America’s “most innovative company” six times between 1996 and 2001. The magazine was correct, just in the wrong way.

Enron’s collapse in 2001 should have served as a warning about these practices. Instead, OBS liabilities grew dramatically, spreading to the center of American finance, now totaling many trillions, though it is impossible to calculate (which is part of the point).11 Of great utility to the practice was the creation of special derivatives—including collateralized debt obligations, swaps, structured products, and so on—that purported to allow the precise division and reallocation of risk for every taste and budget but which in actuality allowed for huge amounts to be wagered against very little capital, through incredibly complex means, on balance sheet and off.

At moderate size, some of these ideas had merit—it’s fine to insure against credit losses through swaps or hedge next year’s crop delivery by selling futures. After the 1990s, reasonable uses were eclipsed by derivatives’ utility in juicing returns through speculation; one need not understand the mechanics of this to appreciate the consequences. A look at the size of the market alone makes it wholly unlikely that any bona fide insurance or hedging was going on. The “notional” size of credit derivatives is larger than world GDP, and while most of these positions are netted against each other and others are unlikely to produce a total loss, there’s clearly a significant mismatch. If you ensure a Camry at the value of a Rolls Royce, are you really buying insurance or are you betting that the car gets stolen before your next payment to GEICO is due? If GEICO wrote you that policy, would it be an insurance company or something closer to a speculator?

The financial establishment now dominated by Boomers had to persuade the accounting profession (also dominated by Boomers) to accept the consignment of these derivatives off balance sheet. Accountants, who had only a generation before set the standard for fairness, prudence, and transparency, rolled over.* The collapses of Lehman Brothers and Bear Stearns were both linked to OBS practices and similar practices would have killed AIG, the giant “insurer,” had the government not bailed it out.

The private sector, as its proponents trumpet (and in a different context, I’m a fan of the private sector), is an engine for innovation, though under the Boomers inventiveness slid quickly into fraud, helped in substantial part by a sustained deregulatory push. Again, warnings abounded. The first wave of financial deregulation in the late 1970s helped precipitate the savings and loan crisis in the succeeding years. The S&L crisis was not primarily the fault of the Boomers, though some Boomers were involved, like Neil Bush, the red dwarf in the ever-dimming Bush galaxy.* The S&Ls, which had just a few years earlier begged for relief from government oppression, were forced to go back to DC and plead for bailouts. The government obliged, and if Boomers did not learn any lessons about undue risk, they deeply appreciated the government’s potential to serve as a backstop to speculation.

Even as the S&L disaster unfolded, Boomers began taking over Wall Street, and in financial engineering they found a vocation in which they could exceed their parents, however dismally. The Boomers pioneered new and riskier ways of doing business, whose consequences would make the S&L crisis seem positively demure. The previously modest market for junk bonds exploded, substantially the creation of Boomer Michael Milken of Drexel Burnham. Junk bonds are debt securities that are not “investment grade,” with greater risks of default than conventional debt. They are speculative instruments and have their place, but their use expanded well beyond those limits, and not surprisingly, many worked out poorly. Milken was subsequently convicted of securities violations and Drexel went under; repackaged with the more pleasing label of “high-yield debt,” junk bonds soldier on today and in mid-2016 were enjoying a bull run.

Wall Street relied heavily on junk bonds to finance leveraged buyouts (LBOs), a process in which companies would be bought, slimmed down, and flipped back laden with debt to the public markets. The great early practitioner of this was KKR, a firm run by two Boomers, Henry Kravis and George Roberts (the first K, Jerome Kohlberg, who was not a Boomer, had resigned over Kravis and Roberts’s decision to pursue larger, riskier, and more hostile takeovers). Although a target of criticism during the 1980s—one of their LBOs was the subject of the book Barbarians at the Gate—KKR has generally done well by its investors; its numerous and less apt imitators, decidedly less so.

The restructuring of companies became something of a fashion after 1980, helped along by deregulation and a certain amount of fuzzy thinking. The fashionable doctrine of “synergies,” which essentially promised something for nothing, became a great enabler for waves of consolidation and recombination. Synergies were the perfect doctrine for the sociopath, combining deceit, avarice, imprudence, and anti-empiricism. The lumbering conglomerates of old failed to understand the right way to combine (true enough); in the new era, synergy-justified mergers would bring only good. Certainly, they could boost overall profits so long as enough costs were cut and workers fired—legitimate enough—but cost-cutting rarely satisfied market expectations, given all the debt and transaction fees involved. With synergies, Boomer financiers explained, new consolidations would not only be leaner, they would be better, more efficient, and (this could only be whispered) closer to monopolies.

It never quite worked out that way, as spectacular failures like the acquisition of venerable Time Warner by upstart America Online and Hewlett-Packard’s acquisition of Compaq showed. Nevertheless, just as Boomer Donald Trump parades his business expertise as a political qualification notwithstanding the financial catastrophes at his casinos, so too did the architect of the Compaq deal, Boomer Carly Fiorina. Briefly a presidential candidate, Fiorina glossed over the price shareholders paid for her bad decisions, perhaps remembering only the handsome payout she received on being fired. That was not Fiorina’s only scandal at HP; there were also the iffy sales of equipment to an embargoed Iran during her tenure, though perhaps that counts as a “foreign policy credential.”12

Irregular Regulation

The S&L crisis had been created, in part, by the loosening of regulatory strictures. Even as the hangover from the S&L crisis lingered until the mid-1990s, the Boomer neoliberal machine and its selective memory were busily forgetting the follies of the past while remembering the lessons that mattered. By the 1990s, Congress was firmly in the hands of the Boomers and could be counted on for two things: (1) watering down regulations, and (2) providing bailouts should anything go wrong. If this sounds like the perverted neoliberalism of Chapter 6, that’s exactly what it was.

As Boomer power grew, so did the deregulatory spirit, with support from both sides of the aisle. After a modest pause under Bush (Greatest Generation edition), deregulatory fever returned with Boomers Gingrich and Clinton. In 1994—a year before the S&L crisis was finally resolved—a Boomer Congress enacted the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act (RN), essentially abolishing restrictions on bank acquisitions across state lines. RN passed with broad bipartisan support, including from the White House, paving the way for financial industry consolidation over the next twenty years. Now, a bank could grow so long as it did not control more than 10 percent of the nation’s deposits—that would be the threshold for “too big to fail.”13 Maybe.

Abstractly, RN was a fine idea; in practice, RN was fraught with moral hazard. Institutions below the 10 percent threshold had already been bailed out, like First Pennsylvania and Continental Illinois. The latter was, until the 2000s, one of the most spectacular and controversial bailouts, and Continental was just a baby bank compared to today’s monsters. Continental collapsed in 1984 after acquiring bad oil and gas loans (just the sort of asset now plaguing several Boomer-run banks).14 Continental’s salvation taught banks and depositors that they would not really face the sort of market discipline that was a core assumption of the free market theories supposedly driving deregulation. RN catalyzed the Boomers’ privatization of gain and socialization of risk.

To make the most of RN, other laws had to be dismantled, like the Glass-Steagall Act (GS). Passed as part of the New Deal, GS restricted banks from engaging in riskier (if potentially more lucrative) activities that were unrelated to their core business. The Federal Reserve opened some questionable loopholes to GS in the 1980s, but the law remained on the books. By 1998—about four years after the government wound up the last of the S&Ls—Citicorp merged with Travelers Insurance to form Citigroup. The combination would have violated what remained of GS, and unless that law were repealed, Citi would have to divest many assets it had just acquired, making the transaction costly and pointless. However, Citi’s CEO was confident the Boomer neoliberal establishment would see the light. It did. By 1999, thanks to intense lobbying of Gingrich, Clinton, et al., the law was officially buried, and the head of Citi sported a trophy lauding himself as the “Shatterer of Glass-Steagall” (hopefully not a conscious invocation of Robert Oppenheimer quoting the Bhagavad Gita during the first A-bomb tests).15

Under Boomer control, banks were free to grow and undertake increasingly speculative projects unrelated to their banking businesses, though they were often free to leverage “safe” money when making these wagers. Banks were also liberated, from 2004 onward, to take on increasing leverage thanks to the SEC’s modification of the net capital rules. The change was requested by banks made bigger and riskier by previous deregulation (one supplicant was Hank Paulson, then at Goldman Sachs and soon to become Treasury secretary, where he arranged a bailout in the same buildings in which the banks had recently begged to be free of Washington). While the media ignored the changes, some banks did not and expanded risk sharply through direct leverage and/or balance-sheet fiddling.16

Meanwhile, in the realm of alternative finance, the hedge fund Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) had collapsed in 1998, the victim of large, levered derivative transactions. LTCM, in short, wagered too much backed up by too little, and the wager went the wrong way. Its three masters were Boomers (one of the Canadian variety) and two had won the Nobel Prize for—of all things—a pricing model for derivatives. LTCM’s failure almost destabilized the financial sector. Only the then-unprecedented intervention of the Fed and industry leaders contained the fiasco. Undeterred, another Boomer Congress deregulated derivatives in 2000 and the market for these items, often conveniently kept OBS, vastly expanded.17

Just before the 2008 crisis, the largest banks were almost all led by Boomers, like Chuck Prince of Citi, Kerry Killinger and Alan Fishman of Washington Mutual (the biggest US bank failure ever), Ken Lewis of Bank of America, Jamie Dimon at JP Morgan Chase, and Lloyd Blankfein at Goldman Sachs, who became CEO after co-Boomer Hank Paulson left for the Treasury in 2006. All expanded their banks, though to what extent and at what risk remained a mystery, certainly to the SEC. SEC chairman Chris Cox, having relaxed capital rules four years earlier, opined as late as 2008 that he had a “good deal of comfort about the capital cushions at these firms,” firms like Bear Stearns, which collapsed days after Cox issued his soothing talk.18 Was Cox out of his depth, lying, or both? We do know, at a minimum, that Cox was a Boomer.

It wasn’t as if some people didn’t sense the possibility of things going south—Goldman bet against the housing market while peddling the other side of the transactions to its clients, and Chuck Prince of Citi said in 2007 that the credit-fueled boom might end but that “as long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and dance. We’re still dancing.”19 Prince’s admission came even as the cracks were opening; he was, effectively, drunk at 2:00 a.m. and ordering another round. Although the situation was clearly fragile, banks’ quarterly reports chirped optimism.

While the deregulatory push from the 1980s to 2008 had grounds in free market philosophy, the Boomer establishment that had pushed neoliberalism was happy to ask the government for help when convenient. Both Republican George Bush II and Democrat Barack Obama oversaw a titanic bailout. Congress authorized the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), $700 billion to mop up the various toxic assets produced and consumed by the financial sector. Cox, free market deregulator circa 2004, turned statist in 2008 and temporarily banned short selling of 799 different financial stocks.20 The SEC’s press release opined that short bets against financial stocks contributed to “price declines in the securities of financial institutions unrelated to true price valuation.”21 Of course, the whole logic of free market theory is that the market knows best and gets to set its own price. Anyway, the failures of important firms made clear that price declines were hardly “unrelated” to proper valuations. Taken alone, government intervention might have been fine. In light of the free market parade that had preceded, it was just another example of the heads-I-win-tails-you-lose thinking that has prevailed over the past three decades. The 2008 crisis had another odd outcome: Although the size of AIG, Citi, and their peers made them “too big to fail” (and thus the taxpayers’ problems), many surviving banks actually got bigger in the immediate aftermath, in part due to mergers that the government helped orchestrate, like BofA’s acquisition of Merrill Lynch and JP Morgan’s purchase of Washington Mutual (or its remains, anyway).

A major problem during recent crises had been the absence of good data. Even as the need for greater understanding became urgent, the resources assigned to regulation and reporting remained wholly insufficient. The growing volume of financial transactions produced nothing like a corresponding increase in the budgets of the primary regulators, and that should have been no surprise. After all, transparency and data are anathema to sociopathic deception and subjectivity.

The Census, the oldest and most basic system of national reporting, has been perhaps the least visible and most important casualty. In 2012, after 133 years and 136 volumes, the Census privatized the majestic Statistical Abstract of the United States, for a grand savings of $2.9 million or 0.0001 percent of the 2012 federal budget. In an era where electronic publication makes the Abstract nearly costless to provide, citizens must fork over $179 for a private copy.22 (It’s still worth it.) The Census still happens; its full results are just harder to access. (It doesn’t help that older data are available only in iffy pdfs or that some spreadsheets are not compatible with recent versions of Excel—which is why so much of the research for this book occurred on an ancient laptop.)

It’s not even clear if budgets had kept pace that many agencies still possessed the requisite will to comprehend their subjects. In the more than eighteen months between April 2007, when the SEC relaxed capital requirements and authorized banks to model their own risks, and the late summer of 2008, when the wheels came off, the special office assigned to monitor the results of deregulation completed zero investigations (it also had no director).23 Even though it is clear that neither government nor firms had adequate insight into systemic risk, the trend has been to less transparency and understanding.

The accounting profession’s craven accommodations did not make it any easier to understand what was going on. Sometimes the auditors simply committed fraud, as happened when Bernie Madoff’s accountants helped his Ponzi scheme. More usually, it took the form of industry opinions that allowed substantial and unwise discretion on the part of financial officers. Older and more conservative standards, like holding assets at book value, gave way to mark-to-market and mark-to-model accounting. The former allowed firms to price their assets at prevailing market prices (fair enough) and received strong support from financial firms when the market was performing well. The latter—well, the industry terminology for mark-to-model was “mark-to-myth.” Whatever CFOs and risk officers needed the model to produce, the subjective adjustment of variables would allow.*

As matters deteriorated between 2006 and 2008, the accounting profession’s governing body continued opening loopholes. These effectively allowed many firms to avoid or reclassify losses during times of market stress. In certain cases, including the highly pertinent case of a crash where no orderly market existed to price assets, firms could assign whatever value they deemed appropriate.24 Given the rise in private transactions not cleared on conventional exchanges, the possibility of “disorderly markets” was not small and neither was the potential for accounting abuse. Taken together with the complexity of the operations of the biggest, most critical banks, that means the system remains to this day at the mercy of sociopathic subjectivity.

It did not help that the Boomers’ psychologically formative years came during a time of great prosperity and that their professional lives were characterized by a long and dubious stock market bubble, allowing critical faculties to wither. Boomer optimism allowed for variables in risk models and accounting statements to be adjusted to their most appealing settings, a parallel to the collective Boomer delusion that the stock and housing markets “only go up.” Equally unhelpful was the collision of attractive economic theories with an ugly sociological reality. The considerable beauty of free market theory does not apply well, even on its own terms, to irrationality, improvidence, and criminal deception—i.e., Boomer financial behavior.

Thus the inevitable disasters of the past thirty years, which bore enormous consequences, almost all of which have, and will continue, to pass to the young. Older Americans had more stock and deposits at risk than younger Americans, so they benefited considerably more from the bailouts. Those bailouts required borrowing—years of tax cuts, deficits, and the scar tissue of financial crises left government with no cushion—so the debt finance that saved older stockholders and depositors will be a cost passed to the young. And this also explains why Boomers tolerated bailout culture: bailouts benefit here and now, with costs pushed into the future via debt the young must repay. Returning to automobile analogies, the financial system became a rental car paid for under an assumed name using someone else’s credit card. The national Rent-a-Dent was treated accordingly.

Any one bailout, tax cut, or similar would have been fine; indeed, orthodox. But it was not “just one”; the crisis was not so much acute as it is ongoing, beginning with the S&L disaster of the mid-1980s and continuing with the LTCM emergency of 1998, the dot-com crash of 2000, and the housing and financial panics of 2008. And yet, over years of Boomer control the response has always been the same: more deregulation, more spending, lower taxes, and no adequate structural reform during the windows of opportunity between scandals.

Despite the quickening tempo of crisis, nothing about Boomer finance changed. Liberated by the constraints of prudence and the evidence of history, the modest deregulation that began under Democrat Jimmy Carter only accelerated. Despite the cautionary tale of collapse and bailout under Republican Ronald Reagan, the strategy of risk and deregulation expanded under Bill Clinton, continued under his fellow Boomer Bush II, and has gone largely uncorrected under Barack Obama. In an act of macroeconomic heterodoxy, in every major case where laissez-faire consistency might have discomfited Wall Street, Washington provided a decidedly statist backstop. The deregulation, risk seeking, and moral hazard transcended party; it wasn’t so much ideology, as outlook. And that outlook was sociopathic.

Monetary Manipulation and Generational Expropriation

Stuck in the middle of this freewheeling disaster is the Federal Reserve, which sets monetary policy for the nation. Since 1977, it has been the unhappy duty of the Fed both to promote growth and ensure price stability (the “dual mandate”), while also serving as an important bank regulator.25 These goals often conflict, given that the Fed can overstimulate the economy by tolerating high inflation or allowing greater leverage. Reconciling these contradictions takes effort, subtlety, and character. However, as the Boomers took over Washington and the Fed, sociopathic thinking elided any contradictions in the dual (or triple) mandate. Sociopathy required everything to go up and right now, whatever the long-term consequences.

Despite its vast legal powers, the Fed enjoys unusual immunity from critical inquiry and comprehensive criticisms tend to be dismissed as fringe theories. Some attacks really are just Gnomes of Zurich nonsense. But some are quite serious, like the claim that the Fed is unduly secretive. Though the Fed’s independence is important, the bank has been unduly opaque and resistant to oversight, and we have no good insight into the workings of the nation’s most important financial player. Even the semiotics suggest a closeted world of conspiracy; e.g., the Fed’s headquarters resemble a Masonic temple. The one time I visited the Fed to meet with Chairman Ben Bernanke, the vast building appeared totally empty (during the height of the 2008 crisis!), and while we were waiting in the boardroom, the chairman appeared unannounced from behind a hidden door. It was like a visit to Oz.

Indeed, Oz and wizardry are how the establishment tends to view the Fed overall, and this may even be how the Fed views itself, which helps nothing. When the Fed does make mistakes, it rarely admits them and only after a suitably sanitizing interlude, as with Bernanke’s public dismay at the bank’s response to the Great Depression, seven decades after the fact. While the Fed might be entitled to the benefit of the doubt, it should never get the sort of uncritical deference that prevailed from the 1980s to the 2000s, when it was viewed as some sort of economic magician. (Alan Greenspan, Fed chairman from 1987 to 2006, was called the “Maestro,” first as a joke, then as a compliment, then sarcastically, and now not at all.) Moreover, because the Fed has a mandate to protect the economy overall and its tools work best in the short term, it tends to protect the largest classes of interests extant at any given time at the expense of the long view. For the past thirty years, that has meant a bias toward protecting the financial well-being of Boomers.

Some argue that the bank is a perpetual bind, trapped between rapacious private enterprise and a slothful Congress, an apologia that manages to be neither compelling nor wholly factual. The Fed can be endlessly inventive when it wants to be, as its responses to the permanent emergency show: quantitative easing and the unprecedented $3.5 trillion expansion of its balance sheet, its recent consideration of negative interest rates, and so on.26 Though Boomer candidate Sanders, who crusaded on the subject of bank risk, apparently had no idea how a “moral economy” might be achieved, the process is simple enough.27 The Fed has long held the tools to restrain the banks, both indirectly, by adjusting interest rates, and directly, through adjustment of reserve requirements, restrictive rule making, and limits on leverage. And indeed, it moves these levers regularly, just not to the benefit of all persons, favoring instead the category of asset holders, comprised heavily of Boomers.

Let’s examine what happened when the Fed properly exercised even one of its tools, margin requirements. Margin rules limit how much a speculator can borrow to fund securities purchases, helping tamp bubbles. Margin-driven speculation got frequent blame as a cause of the 1929 crash, so between 1945 and 1974, the Fed adjusted margin every few years, from as low as 40 percent in early 1945 to as high as 100 percent in 1946.28 Since 1974, margin requirements have been left unadjusted, at 50 percent.29 During the bubble of the 1990s, the economist Robert Shiller argued the Fed should revive margin tools. A “senior economist and adviser” from the Fed’s Boston bank disagreed, stating that “the capacity to borrow against securities has also risen as a result of rising stock prices. It is not clear this exposes the financial system to more risk.”30 Such was a Fed economist’s view as of September 2000, as the stock market was collapsing.

A tame economy and stock market gave the Fed no good reason to adjust margin rates between 1974 and 1985; since then, it has had plenty of irrational exuberance to contend with, as even Chairman Greenspan acknowledged. And though the chair has been held by a Boomer only since 2006, Boomers colonized the Fed’s other offices much earlier. Under their watch, and despite crashes and bubbles and crashes in 1985–1987, 1998–2000, 2006–2008, and 2012–2016 (more on that in a minute), the Fed has still not adjusted margin rates.

The margin requirement may be a particularly well-tailored tool for stocks, but it is only one of the Fed’s many bubble-fighting weapons generally. If the Fed wants to restrain banks, it can adjust reserve requirements, interest rates, etc. If it wants to target froth in certain assets, like the housing bubble that grew from 1998 to 2006, it can limit the value it assigns to syndicated mortgages and other similar assets posted as collateral with the bank. Given the enormous deference the Fed enjoys, it could probably prevent or deflate a bubble in any asset simply by announcing its intention of doing so.

However, it’s far from clear that the Boomer Fed wants restraint. It has repeatedly skewed toward a permissiveness whose prime beneficiaries are the Boomers. That is especially the case with the stock market, which has been on a long, if uneven, tear. Had economic growth driven stock appreciation, that would be fine, but much of the growth has been due to an expansion of valuations untethered from growth. (The companies participate in the collective delusion by emphasizing pro forma accounting measurements to exclude “unrepresentative”—i.e., unflattering—results, with the gap between pro forma and GAAP standards being its widest in early 2016 since the ominous dates of 2001–2002 and 2008.31) Measured by the cyclically adjusted price-to-earnings (P/E) ratio the stock market seems overpriced, rising from a postwar average of ~15 to 44.2 by the end of 1999 (higher even than in 1929), and remaining elevated, notwithstanding the Great Recession, at 26.6 as of the fall of 2016.32 Statisticians frequently look for mean reversions, the tendency of extreme conditions to return to long-term averages, and a reversion to postwar averages would imply a very steep drop in prices, all else being equal. But all else is not equal and a mean reversion is the last thing policymakers desire: Real rates are at rock bottom and this has provided a tailwind to stock valuations. The institution responsible, of course, is the Fed, which is now a prisoner of its own policies, and perversely, the justification for low rates gets better the longer the process drags out.

Valuation changes have generational consequences. Stocks were relatively cheap in the early 1980s, when median Boomers were thirty-somethings buying stocks (cyclically adjusted P/E ratios ran 9 to 12). Stocks are now expensive, as the median Boomer turns sixty-five and begins liquidating. For each successful seller there must, of course, be a buyer, and domestically, the natural buyers are the young. The generational effect is that the Boomers bought low and sold high thanks to accommodating public and private actors (which they controlled). Should P/E ratios revert to historical norms, the generational transfer will be fully realized. Reversion will make it vastly harder for the young to build retirement savings, as any return to normal valuations will create losses in their existing portfolios, putting young savers even further behind. The young can always invest in something other than stocks, but the long-term trend in interest rates limits their options. Since 2008, rates on bank deposits have been near zero. The same thing applies to bond yields, with the additional difficulty that if interest rates should ever rise, the value of existing bond portfolios will fall.* Generationally, then, both sellers and buyers are forced to participate, with the key difference being that in recent years the transactions have taken place at prices far more beneficial to the former.

A similar dynamic has unfolded in the housing market. While the sources like Case-Shiller, the Census, and the Dallas Fed have their own arcane disputes over the exact level of house prices, they generally agree on the direction and magnitude of house-price changes: up, and by a lot. From the 1980s to the mid-1990s, home prices grew roughly in line with the economy. After 1997, when almost all the Boomers who wanted to purchase housing had already done so (the youngest were by then thirty-three and the oldest, fifty-seven), home prices rose dramatically. It’s not that growth in the economy or population accelerated suddenly or permanently. The better explanation was government subsidy.

The Boomer-controlled government expanded housing subsidies during the Boomers’ prime home-owning years: property tax caps, mortgage interest deductions, tax exemptions on sales, and so on all favored existing and wealthier homeowners. The government also cultivated the sentimental idea of homeownership as a national virtue. So while renting is often a better financial decision, Clinton, Bush II, and so on extolled this peculiar American dream, and consumers came to view home ownership not just as a necessity or luxury consumable, but as a surefire investment, even a kind of entitlement. People bought bigger and more expensive houses, a consumption problem of its own, while rent control, property tax freezes, zoning restrictions, and other inefficient limits favored existing residents. And the banks willingly facilitated, often reducing down payments from the conventional 20 percent to as low as 3.5 percent or even 0 percent—i.e., allowing leverage to increase from 4:1 to 27.6:1, or in the case of zero down, ∞:1. Many banks competed on the ease of approval, forgoing income verification in favor of borrowers’ self-reporting.

When bets turned sour, the Fed intervened, to the great benefit of Boomers. The bank purchased mortgage assets to hold the market together, and by 2016, housing had almost entirely recovered the losses from the period 2007–2012, for reasons again mostly untethered from economic fundamentals.* The Boomers will soon become liquidators of real estate at these conveniently refreshed prices, harvesting substantial cash from credulous new buyers. Worse, the costs of previous home subsidies will be borne by the young, in the form of national debt passed along due to costs of housing tax subsidies and other goodies handed out by the Boomers to the Boomers.

The other gift to the Boomers—especially the oldest Boomers—has been an interest rate environment helpfully aligned with their life cycle. In the mid-1970s, many real interest rates were often quite low.33 As the Boomers were young and accumulating debt, this was extremely helpful; they were all but paid to borrow. Rates spiked from 1980 to 1982 before a sustained decline during the period of Boomer debt accumulation; rates were higher but moving quickly in the right direction, and that was what mattered.34 At the same time, the economy was growing, albeit in historically unspectacular fashion, making it easier to maintain that debt. Interest rates have fallen since 2008; the difference this time is that the economy is very weak, meaning new debt is not nearly as easy to service as it was during the period of rate declines from the 1980s to 1994. (Another difference between Boomer-then and Millenial-now: In the transition from net borrower to net saver, older generations benefited from meaningful real interest on their cash deposits—a helpful bonus many Millenials, habituated to banks offering 0.5 percent APYs, have never experienced.)

Ultra-low rates pose challenges for all ages, but they have least effect on those with net savings. Should the United States tip into outright deflation, so long as nominal rates are zero or above, the burden of debt will grow in real terms. At the same time, the value of deposits would automatically rise. In the long term, no one wins, but in the short term terms, savers—i.e., older Americans—do the best. Also, as Keynes noted, in the long run we are all dead, and the Boomers sooner than everyone else.

A final note on monetary policy: In many ways, the Fed’s arsenal of recession-combating tools, including its credibility as an institution, represents an asset. Since 2008, the Fed has been spending down this asset to prop up the economy, especially stocks and houses owned by Boomers. The Fed exhausted its conventional arsenal (interest rate cuts) fairly quickly, forcing it to experiment from 2008 with quantitative easing, purchasing vast amounts of risk assets like mortgage paper for its own account. The risks of inaction were certainly real, though the benefits, while also meaningful, remain hard to quantify and really evaluate. Regardless, the Fed has now used all of its good tools, leaving less to fight whatever comes next. (At the same time, the bubble-fighting tool kit, as we have seen, went essentially untouched during the Boomer era.) In the event of another crisis in the medium-term, the next step is aggressive and unprecedented: setting nominal interest rates at less than zero. Japan and parts of Europe have begun this experiment, and initial results do not encourage. So, like the Army, the Fed has been depleted by Boomer improvidence, leaving future generations without good means to combat the next and inevitable recession. Obviously, the working young will suffer the most. The Boomers, meanwhile, are embarking on the long cruise of a tax-subsidized retirement.

CHAPTER FOURTEEN

DETENTION, AFTER-SCHOOL AND OTHERWISE

He who opens a school door, closes a prison.

—Victor Hugo1

Had Victor Hugo witnessed Boomer educational and penal policy, he might have reconsidered the truth of the foregoing, thrown up his hands and inverted the whole sentiment, added a stream of qualifiers, or just parroted Émile Zola in a hearty J’accuse. Under Boomer control schools and jails have intertwined, the degrading former providing sustenance for the swollen latter. Boomer schools and jails are no longer systems of uplift and remediation; they have become mechanisms of mass containment and deferred liability.

Educational erosion began when the Boomers were themselves in school, wasting the opportunities their parents granted, a casual disregard of school that continued in more virulent form when Boomers took power. Despite ritual genuflections before the altar of excellence, Boomers revealed their fundamental unseriousness in education policies that ranged from negligent to ludicrous. After decades of promises made and broken, the United States continues to underperform against its peers. What improvements have been achieved are often misleading, the product of lowered bars, statistical manipulations, and in some cases, outright fraud.

As economy and education faltered under the Boomers, a parallel system rose to contain the factory seconds, kept company by whatever portions of society Boomers found it expedient to impound. That parallel system is history’s largest penal regime, and it extends well beyond the needs of deterrence and containment. Erected at enormous cost to the fisc (as usual, mostly debt financed), the corrections system has become a state within a state; indeed, in 2014, it was America’s thirty-sixth most populous state, larger than New Mexico, and if those in probationary regimes are included, its fourteenth largest, just ahead of Massachusetts.2 Many of its charges could have been saved by the schools the Boomers failed, by social programs the Boomers let decay, or by the exercise of empathetic clemency instead of automatic punishments that appealed to the Boomers’ crudest Old Testament instincts. Instead, Boomer policy created a conveyor belt that leads from school detention to its lifetime equivalent.

Boomers as Students

The educational crisis began in the early 1960s, the Boomers’ own school years, when American scholastic performance began a downward slide. At least for the white, middle-class majority, it was as much the students failing the system as vice versa. By the time America realized Boomer test scores constituted a national embarrassment, the Boomers themselves were taking over the instruments of school policy. It was therefore society’s great misfortune that demographics and timing consigned responsibility for any educational renaissance to the hands of the generation whose underperformance had prompted calls for reform in the first place.

Aside from crude measures like literacy, the longest continuous data on American educational achievement are SAT scores, and what they show is a decline that overlapped almost perfectly with the period Boomers took those tests. After a period of stability from 1952 to 1963, scores fell nearly continuously for two decades, a slide that began just after the first Boomers sat for the SAT (using my date of 1940 for the start of the Boom, or, using the conventional definition of 1946, exactly when Boomers started taking the test) and ended in 1982–1983, precisely when the last Boomers left high school.3 If one wanted to define the Boom by other than mere fertility statistics, the downward curve of SAT scores would identify essentially the same population.

While the slide was alarming, observers correctly detected a partial triumph hidden within the embarrassment of overall scores. Thanks to integration and greater gender equality, the pool of SAT takers had become more inclusive from the 1950s onward. Because these new kinds of takers traditionally scored lower (women on math, minorities on math and verbal, a discrepancy due in part to historical discrimination), their scores temporarily depressed results overall.* But that was only part of the story. Per the College Board, which administers the SAT, “compositional changes” of these kinds explained between 66 and 75 percent percent of the decline from 1963 to 1970 and “only about a quarter” of the even steeper decline after 1970 (in which year the median Boomer would have been seventeen or eighteen and of prime test-taking age).4 Declines after 1970 affected “virtually all categories of SAT takers,” top students, mediocre students, blacks, whites, almost any way you sliced it.5 The SAT slide was paralleled in ACT scores.6 GRE scores, in line with Boomer progression through the education system, began declining somewhat later, with “almost half the drop concentrated in 1969–1970,” as older Boomers would have begun sitting for those tests.7 College Board analysts tried correction for any variables they could, even subjecting students to both the 1963 and 1973 tests as a control, and if anything that made matters worse—the 1973 test appeared to give a lift of eight to twelve points versus the 1963 test (it was, effectively, more generous with points).8 In the end, much of the decline was attributed to “pervasive” factors that the Educational Testing Service danced around, but can really only be read as: Boomers.9

Scholastic Inaptitude

What’s going on here? The first Boomers starting taking the SATs around 1957–1959 and the last around 1981–1983. The declines in SAT scores defined Boomers in their own way; once the Boomers were no longer of traditional test-taking age, scores improved (modestly). The SAT subsequently tinkered with its scoring formulas, but during the period presented, the methodology was consistent—i.e., the changes were driven not by the test, but by the test takers.10

The Boomers’ poor SAT scores were somewhat surprising, given the context. America was affluent and schools reasonably provisioned. Getting into college, for which SATs served as a gateway, had become widely important: College provided an exemption to the draft (if one were so inclined—and as we know from Chapter 3, millions were) and the growing wage premium for college degrees offered the easiest path to higher incomes in the era of stagflation. Was it perhaps something about the test takers themselves, televisual, self-interested, permissively raised, bottle-fed, and politically distracted? The correspondence between Boomer test-taking and falling scores is suggestive, as it is what happened next.

As soon as the Boomers left high school, SAT scores rose—i.e., matters improved before the tentative reforms of the late 1970s could work any real magic. And while scores continued improving over the next decades, the gains should not be seen as some unqualified success for Boomer educational policy. Absolute scores remain unimpressive overall and flatter only relative to the Boomer-era fiasco. The failure to achieve real excellence represents a core disaster of Boomer policy and the waste of huge amounts of time, money, and opportunity.

Boomers as Policy Makers

In 1979, the SAT embarrassment and other schooling fiascos forced Jimmy Carter to act. He gave education (formerly a modest part of the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare) its own Cabinet-level agency, elevating what had once been an almost purely local matter into one of national importance. Given the success of prior efforts like compulsory primary and secondary education, the establishment of land grant colleges, and the progression of American research universities from second-rate status to international leadership, national optimism in 1979 was wholly understandable. What America had done before, could it not do again? Critics worried that Reagan would derail the project, as Reagan’s first campaign had a plank calling for abolition of Carter’s new department. Reagan never did—in fact, he chartered a bipartisan National Commission on Excellence in Education in his first year as president.11

In 1983, the Commission produced A Nation at Risk, a remarkable document that offered a candid assessment of American secondary education and provided wholly sensible ideas for reform. Quite a bit of ANAR remains depressingly current—if you strip out the dates, parts could have been written yesterday. That is the core of ANAR’s present relevance: more than three decades later, most of it a period of almost complete Boomer power, the problems remain the same while many of ANAR’s recommendations languish ignored and untried. It was not that Boomers did not know what to do, it was that they did not do it.

The report found that much of the American high school curriculum was mediocre and that nonacademic classes like “bachelor living” could, if a student wished, account for a substantial portion of graduation credits.12 The previous generation should have kept these nonclasses off the menu, but nevertheless, it was the Boomers who chose to take them. A Nation at Risk also bemoaned the imposition of “minimum competency” standards, which fell “short of what is needed, as the ‘minimum’ tends to become the ‘maximum,’ thus lowering educational standards for all.”13 The report also worried about America’s short school year (almost 40 percent fewer hours than some international peers), the paucity of homework, persistent grade inflation, and the automatic shuffling along of children to the next grade (as the College Board noted, rather aptly, automatic advancement was perceived as an “entitlement, rather than something to be earned—or denied,” and we know how Boomers feel about entitlements).14 Some of these problems were not the fault of Boomer policymakers, but once ANAR made the problems clear, they became the Boomers’ responsibility. Could the United States return to its former position of eminence in international league tables? Well, that depended on who was in charge, and from the 1980s, it was increasingly the Boomers.

The Boomers—beginning to rear children of their own—clamored for reform, or at least its Kabuki equivalent. Of course, as we have seen, they were unwilling to tax themselves to furnish necessary funds, for schools or anything else. Nor would Boomers of any political stripe engage with the substance of education itself, as that would require money, effort, compromise, and other irksome undertakings. For Democrats, ANAR’s demand for longer school days and teacher accountability would require confronting the teachers’ unions, a prospect from which Democrats recoiled. For Republicans, more teaching days would inevitably require higher pay, and that would mean higher taxes, anathema to the Republicans and, over time, resisted too by Boomer Democrats. The sociopathic solution would be theatre without sacrifice (or results) and the constant shuffling of responsibility between federal and local governments, to ensure minimum accountability.

Much as Boomer economic neoliberalism provided a nothing-for-nothing “third way,” so educational neoliberalism would provide its own third way, to similar effect. The charge was led by Bill Bennett, the nation’s third secretary of education, appointed two years after ANAR came out. Rather than pursue ANAR’s recommendations, Bennett (a Boomer, naturally) and his successors held that the market would improve education, in the form of vouchers, school choice, charter schools, the federalist laboratory of the states in edifying competition with each other, and all the other neoliberal nostrums manufactured from the 1980s on and embraced by both parties. It was a risky bet, but then again, Bill Bennett, erstwhile educator and moral crusader, was nothing if not a risk taker, as his $8 million in gambling losses would subsequently reveal.15

However convenient it would be to dismiss Bennett as a Reaganite anomaly, the neoliberal experiment accelerated as Boomers gained power, under Democrats and Republicans, in states, blue, red, purple, and all the other dismal colors of the Boomer political rainbow, starting with charter school initiatives, passed in many cases by direct referendum—and thus not attributable to politicians alone. Minnesota and California granted the first state charters in 1991–1992; as of 2016, forty-three states and the District of Columbia have them, a period that coincided with near-total Boomer control of state politics. Charter schools have records that are, at best, mixed. Some are effective institutions, others achieve a facsimile of success by siphoning off the naturally talented and jettisoning the less apt, and many are simply terrible. Overall, their performance is not radically different from that of public schools.16 Various other initiatives with merit pay and tenure reform produced equally mixed results.17 Some of these projects were worth trying, but after decades without satisfying results, it’s difficult to applaud policy makers for repeating the same experiments and expecting better outcomes.

The experiments Boomers did not want, or bother, to run were the substantive reforms outlined in ANAR. Levels of homework, length and number of school days, teacher compensation, and curricula are not substantially better than they were decades ago—the school year remains the same, teacher compensation remains moderate relative to better-performing nations (in part because American teachers work less—Leftists tend to overlook this point), and hours of homework have not budged.18 As for curricula, a 2016 survey by the Education Trust found that “students are meandering toward graduation,” with high schools “prioritizing credit accrual” instead of “access to a cohesive curriculum that aligns high school coursework and students’ future goals.”19 The survey concluded that 47 percent of students had no “cohesive curriculum” and at most, 39 percent had a college-ready curriculum.20 If this sounds familiar, it’s because ANAR said the same thing decades ago.

Some problems identified in the 1980s actually got worse, particularly grade inflation. In Boomer culture, all children are “special,” bound for college and greatness. Therefore no child could receive any grade to the contrary. UC Berkeley, for instance, is a good school but hardly the most selective in the country, yet its 2015 freshmen had gross average high school GPAs of 3.91 and 4.41 on a “weighted” basis—in other words, the nation’s twentieth-best university had freshmen whose transcripts were essentially perfect, and on some metrics, beyond perfect.21 This is why focusing on test scores rather than transcripts has become so important: Not only are curricula poor, grades reflect no objective reality.

As for the schools themselves, budget limits consigned them to physical decay, which could not have helped the learning process. Returning to the Infrastructure Report Card, the physical plant of schools has traveled from a D in 1988 to an F in 1998, and then hovered around D since, though ASCE doesn’t quite know, because not enough data are available.22 It was a tad ungrateful of the Boomers—for whom about half of existing school capacity was built—to let their former schoolhouses languish in squalor.*,23

Against international peers, the United States has not fulfilled any education secretary’s goal of excellence. Not only have SAT scores failed to surpass their 1950s peaks (no surprise given the lingering curricular issues), but on international scales, the United States remains middling at best. The latest international comparisons are the Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) tests, and from 2000 to 2012, the years for which PISA data are available, they showed that the United States achieved “no significant change in [US] performances over time” despite endless state and federal initiatives, with reading scores average and math performance “below average” (PISA is being polite: The United States was twenty-seventh out of thirty-four developed nations).24

It could come as no surprise that in 2010, Education Secretary Arne Duncan found himself in the position of repeating the same vows as all of his predecessors. Duncan promised that the United States would (somehow, one day) “lead the world in educational attainment,” as “nothing, nothing, is more important in the long-run to American prosperity than boosting the skills and attainment of the nation’s students.”25 True, but measured by action, “nothing, nothing” is more important to Boomers than low taxes, entitlement spending, and debt-fueled consumption.*,26

There have been only three, highly dubious, areas of improvement: class size, certain nominal test scores, and gross graduation rates. Class size has become something of a fetish, and the overall pupil/teacher ratio has declined at a slow rate since the 1970s. It’s now—with enormous variation between grades, schools, and geographies—about 20:1.27 However, it’s not clear how important this metric is. A Nation At Risk didn’t trouble itself over class size—it focused on teacher quality; anyway, during America’s scholastic heyday, class sizes were much larger in both public and private schools, 26:1 and 31:1 in 1960.28 The problem in 1983 is still the problem now; teachers are notionally competent in methods of pedagogy, but not necessarily the substance of the class they teach—and therefore it doesn’t matter whether there are twenty students in the room or forty.

As for test scores, thirty-odd years of reform produced a far from enviable record. Among younger students, reading and math scores have drifted upward, but by age seventeen—the age that really matters as it roughly mirrors the conclusion of K–12 education—progress has been slight to nonexistent.29 The one major improvement has been a narrowing of the white-minority achievement gap, though it’s convergence of the wrong type, with white groups treading water and most minority groups converging on majoritarian mediocrity.30

At least the race gap has converged in its own unsatisfactory way; gaps between rich and the not-rich have widened. As economic inequality has vastly increased under the Boomers, and as younger couples increasingly tend to pair with mates of comparable educational and economic attainments (both strong predictors of a child’s success), we can only expect these gaps to grow. Encouraging statistics do pop up from time to time, though few withstand investigation. For example, graduation rates have improved. As high school seniors do not possess the full benefit of a proper education, those results provide only limited consolation. All in all, the picture is disheartening: some improvement in math, no improvement in reading, a narrowing minority performance gap (albeit to the wrong levels), a widening socioeconomic gap poised to grow wider still, and graduation rates leached of meaning—after thirty-odd years of “reform.”

As failures mounted, promises grew. In January 1989, Bush I assumed office as the “education president” and encouraged governors to endorse goals where, by the year 2000, American children would lead the world in math and science achievement, all children would be prepared for “challenging subject matter,” high school graduation rates would reach 90 percent, and so on.31 How this would be achieved was left badly unaddressed and, of course, Bush I’s goals went unfulfilled (math, thirty-fifth; science, twenty-seventh; graduation rates 81 percent and of dubious meaning anyway; children prepared for challenging material, far from all, as we will see).32 The goal of prepping “all” children to high levels, by the way, did not reveal seriousness of purpose, but its absence. The goals were unachievable and would grow only more absurd as Boomers colonized education departments. That’s not to say that real improvement could not be achieved, only that the targets set were wrong and the results achieved failed to impress.

Thus, while 2000 brought no computerized reckoning (being a matter of profits, Y2K was taken seriously), that year did reveal Bush I’s promises as unfulfilled. The problems were therefore consigned to the hands of… Bush II. In 2001, the new Bush ginned up the No Child Left Behind Act, offering equally outlandish promises: that “all” students would be “proficient” by graduation, instructed by “highly qualified” teachers (or “distinguished” ones, query what distinguished them).33 It passed with overwhelming, bipartisan support. The federal government would set the standards, the states would figure out how to achieve them, and Washington would apply various carrots and sticks along the way. It was the perfect combination of Boomer foibles—anti-empirical fantasy and/or cynicism (no society can make “all” of a group “proficient”), neoliberal federalist magic (incentives! states’ rights!), and, of course, de minimis diversion of tax receipts away from the entitlements programs that were becoming matters of urgency for undersaved Boomers. Echoing the fantasy-by-fiat of Soviet planning, No Child demanded triumph by 2014.

The success of the No Child act may be inferred from its uncontested repeal and replacement in 2015. It was reincarnated as the Every Child Succeeds Act, another title of utterly fraudulent Boomer promise, passed (again) with bipartisan support and signed by President Obama. The new act retained testing but removed certain penalties for poorly performing schools, forbade federal imposition of curricula, and devolved many powers to the states (again, tried before, failed before).34 The states remain mired in the process of figuring out what to do, because Every Child Succeeds does not provide adequate funds, guidance, or accountability. The one thing that is certain is that “every” child will not “succeed.”

In any event, the definition of educational “success” in Boomer education policy is roughly the same as Bush II’s “mission accomplished” was in Iraq—some transient bare minimum, defined as whatever the conditions on the ground already were or could be made out to be, after which matters can be left to devolve on their own. Because Washington (like Moscow) would impose some penalties for failure, the Boomer educational machine relied on the same strategies as the Boomer financial machine: Take what numbers you have, cast them as victory if remotely plausible, and adjust them to the desired level if not, i.e., fraud. A parade of scandals ensued, with teachers focusing overwhelmingly on how to take tests instead of the substance tested, a parallel to teachers’ own training in methods of teaching, rather than achieving mastery of the subject to be taught. If that cynical ploy failed, higher scores could be realized through blatant cheating, like leaving answer sheets out for students to copy or simply fabricating scores (in Atlanta, the results were numerous indictments, pleas, sentencing, etc.).35 Even with cheating—some schools inflating their scores in utterly implausible ways in just a few quarters, tactics that might have shamed Enron—schools did not meet Bush I or II’s promises, and they will not meet Obama’s, either.

The murky, misguided, sentimental, and fraudulent nature of Boomer educational goals more or less guarantee bizarre outcomes. Now, not only must no child be left behind (didn’t happen) and every child succeed (not happening now), every child must go to college (will never happen). Universal college education has become the last uncontroversial virtue under the Boomers, even though it is not achievable for reasons of logistics, attitude, aptitude, and personal and national economics. Other nations know this and divide students early on into vocational and other tracks suited to children’s abilities and needs, as Germany does with its Realschulen, Hauptschulen, Gymnasien, and vocational training in the Duale Ausbildung. These systems are more efficient and effective, though their realism offends Boomer sentimentality. Boomer-run schools cannot be complicit in confirming displeasing realities, like the fact that not all children can, want, or should go to college. Anyway, the marketplace can be relied upon to supply its own brutal curriculum soon enough.

The college fetish is an anomaly, as only over the past few decades has the ostensible purpose of K–12 education become the production of a nation of college graduates—or more precisely, those touched by college, however slightly. In 2009, President Obama called upon every American not to graduate from a good college, but simply to go “one year or more” beyond high school.36 While the president offered career training as an option, an American culture extolling every child’s specialness must have understood the president to mean a year at college.

Obama justified his objective on the grounds that “this country needs and values the talents of every American,” a statement that can be described as naїvely aspirational at best and totally disingenuous at worst.37 Leaving aside normative issues, compensation data show that while America values the talents of college graduates generally, it does not particularly value the services of those who have not finished college. Since 1980, wages have fallen for groups without a college degree, and that includes declines for those with only “some college.”38 In virtually every case, Obama’s one year of college will produce debt, probably add little to knowledge that could and should have been acquired during high school, and is unlikely to produce wage gains: Therefore, it is sentimentality with a price.

Even assuming students do complete college, what college, what major, and how financed matter as much as or more than simply collecting a credential from a random institution. On a pure income basis, not all colleges or majors justify their expense, in terms of direct and opportunity costs. An English degree from a second-tier liberal arts college is generally a consumption good, which is fine by itself, but cannot be justified on policy grounds, and possibly not even social ones.

The worst offenders are not the English departments at Bennington and Bard; the cardinal sinners are for-profit colleges. Because the United States has not adequately invested in conventional nonprofit institutions like community colleges, for-profit colleges have been absorbing the excess supply of the college bound. Between 1998 and 2008, postsecondary enrollment increased 32 percent generally, but 270 percent at for-profit colleges.39 By 2010, almost a tenth of college students enrolled in for-profit institutions.40 These neoliberal confections transform vast amounts of public dollars into private gain, little of which is realized by the students much less the public. Part of the reason is that these institutions provide very little education at considerable cost. Per a Senate committee, “evidence suggests that for-profit schools charge higher tuition than comparable public schools, spend a large share of revenues on expenses unrelated to teaching, experience high dropout rates, and, in some cases, employ abusive recruiting and debt-management practices.”41 Half of student borrowers who entered repayment in 2007 and had defaulted by 2009 had attended for-profit institutions (despite being just under 10 percent of the student population) and for-profit colleges, and by the latter year, for-profit institutions were consuming almost a quarter of federal loans and grants.*,42

Many for-profit colleges are either nonaccredited, or functionally so, and worse than useless. When one of the largest providers, Corinthian Colleges, went bust it left its students indebted and taxpayers holding a very large bag. (Along the way, this showed that these institutions, which are not “colleges,” are also often not, except for their executives, “for profit”). Nor could students pick up where Corinthian left off, as that institution’s loose academic standards made its coursework difficult to transfer and functionally valueless.43 Although for-profit colleges have existed for some time, their arrival as a significant part of the educational landscape is pure Boomer.44 If the government investigations, private lawsuits, and other actions have any merit at all, the Boomers’ for-profit innovations range from the incompetent to the fraudulent.

The flip side of the terrible for-profit colleges are the indignities visited on traditional public institutions and their students. In the 1960s, when Boomers were on campus, public colleges charged nominal, and often zero, annual tuition; today, in-state tuition runs around $13,500. The existence of tuition itself is not necessarily bad, though it is hard to reconcile with the rhetoric about a universal college experience. It is also no substitute for public investment, especially when it comes to adding entirely new schools, which take billions of dollars to create (for tuition alone to support that expense, students would need to pay several hundred thousand dollars annually). In the two most significant public university systems, those of California and Texas, low funding has permitted the creation of only one genuinely new campus during Boomer reign, the highly dispiriting UC Merced.* (Compare this to the list of University of California campuses opened between 1900 and 1965: UCLA, UCSB, UC Riverside, UC Davis, UCSD, UC Irvine, and UCSC.) Deposited in a dusty hellhole, opened almost two decades after authorized, accredited six years after inauguration, and with a decidedly unselective 2015 admissions rate of 64.6 percent, vs. about 17 percent for UC Berkeley and UCLA, Merced is essentially doomed to failure.45 Even as the populations of California and Texas dramatically increased—the latter roughly doubled from 1980 to 2015—systems have not kept up.

While conventional public colleges may be overcrowded and underfunded, they do vastly better than their for-profit equivalents. Unfortunately, here again, the doctrine of college-for-all reveals a seedy Boomerism. Much of that one year of postsecondary work Obama called for will be remedial, for the simple reason that K–12 education has not been doing its job, nor has it done so for some time. At least 20 percent of students at colleges arrive unprepared, wasting space and money.46 The job of topping up high school education often falls to (usually underpaid) adjuncts and part-timers, an old practice that reached new and astonishing scale under Boomer administrators. Adjuncts have been hired in droves, now representing something like 40–50 percent of instructional faculty, depending on the survey and the institutions.47

Because the vast majority of new appointments are no longer for conventional, tenure-track positions, the proportion of adjuncts—precisely the type of instructor usually assigned to teach Obama’s magical first year of college—will continue rising. The presence of adjunct faculty does not bode well for students, as freshmen taught by adjuncts have a lesser propensity to continue to a sophomore year, though this is not necessarily the fault of the adjuncts. However, there has been one major expansion in permanent staff growth, in noninstructional personnel, comprised of various administrative positions created, and subsequently occupied, by Boomers to oversee the growing fraction of campus life that does not involve actual teaching.

Presiding over the adjunct bazaars are, of course, the Boomers in capacities administrative and otherwise. To create the adjunct market, there must be demand and supply. Demand is provided by things like Obama’s sentimental injunction to get that “one year” of college and by for-profit universities that need cheap labor. It is further stoked by traditional universities, which consign many introductory undergraduate classes (beneath the dignity of Boomer professors) to low-paid adjuncts. The Boomer professorate, meanwhile, focuses on producing the supply of graduate students required to serve as adjuncts, few of whom are likely to get tenure themselves, since Boomer professors seem determined to die in their endowed chairs.48 That many older professors are expensive, unproductive and, in fields like mathematics, decades past their prime disturbs not one whit a bloated administrative apparatus.

Student Debt

What is the net result? Too many badly equipped students and an explosion of debt. We saw the bill in Chapter 7; now we know the reason. The $1.3+ trillion in educational debt in the first quarter of 2016, which has overtaken credit card debt over the past decade, burdens both students and society—though Boomers+ least of all.49

Defaults have already begun, because the education funded by those loans has been so dubious and the Boomer economy so inadequate to the task of providing good jobs. Potential losses run into the hundreds of billions, and while these liabilities will be amortized over time, the burden will hit younger taxpayers the most. Meanwhile, the gains have been transferred to the Boomer-dominated educational bureaucracy and leadership of for-profit institutions.

A foreign observer may think American policy had been run by people who had no experience in education or simply hated it. That observer would be wrong. The White House has been occupied by an endless parade of former educators. Since 1952, educators-in-chief included: Dwight Eisenhower (president of Columbia University); Lyndon Johnson (high school teacher); George H. W. Bush (briefly a business school lecturer); Bill Clinton (law school professor); Barack Obama (same). So, for about half of the time since Eisenhower’s inauguration, the White House has been occupied by a former teacher of some kind or other. Bush II was not an educator, but was married to one, so if you include Laura, you could argue educators have resided in the White House for about two-thirds of the period between 1952 and 2016. And that’s leaving aside the degraded future, the contest of 2016 having been between various ersatz educators, Hillary Clinton (who, notwithstanding her failure of the DC bar exam, taught law in Arkansas, whose less demanding test she did pass) and Donald Trump (of the distinctly Boomerish Trump “University”), who fended off challenges from yet more ex-teachers like Ted Cruz (adjunct law professor), and Bernie Sanders (briefly a college lecturer).

The Changing Shape of Consumer Credit

What’s going on here? Sadly, this chart needs little explanation: student debt, formerly so minor the government barely kept statistics at all, has become thanks to Boomer policies a giant feature of the debt landscape.50

Not all presidents or candidates were great educators; then again, statistics show that many full-time educators aren’t great educators, either. The only modern presidents to really succeed in education (in limited ways) were Eisenhower and Johnson; the former, because he had very specific needs and curricular goals in mind (the disciplines necessary to win the Space Race and Cold War) and the latter because he helped alleviate the discrimination and poverty that had made it impossible for many students to learn at all—and both, because they spent real money to achieve meaningful and specific outcomes. All the other educator-leaders either had Boomer students to contend with (eventually, an insurmountable task) or were Boomers themselves, who pursued rhetoric over results.

A Return to A Nation at Risk

What can be done? In theory, education is still mostly a state matter. Were the federal government not on the hook, via welfare and other programs, for the various failures churned out by the states’ “laboratories of democracy,” that would be one thing. Such is not the case. It is time for Washington to intervene or set adrift states that refuse to take education seriously. Washington has the power. Unlike the states, the federal government can borrow as much as it likes, and has long provided the marginal dollar, meaning that it can set policies if it chooses. If it could change state drinking ages by threatening to withhold highway dollars, it can and should do the same with state schools.

What Washington cannot easily change is the culture itself—specifically the culture created by the Boomers. Until that happens, the parade of mediocrity, underfunding, and social failure will continue, thirty-five years of wasted opportunities whose moral and financial debts will be handed off to the young.

Serving No One by Serving Time

Instead of providing education and opportunity, Boomers focused their energies on the creation of an unforgiving penal state, furnished with intolerant laws and panoptic enforcers to supply the inmates. For many, school is just the waiting room before formal incarceration. Perhaps mass detention would be acceptable if prison served as an effective deterrent or society lacked alternatives; neither is or was true. While society had better options, the Boomers favored ever-stricter laws and processed ever more people into the prison system, the spectacle of law and order always being more satisfying to Boomer psychology than any reality of justice or efficacy. While Reagan often gets the blame for the rise of imprisonment, it was Boomers who (frequently in bipartisan accord) passed the most odious laws and Boomer administrations that presided over the most spectacular and fruitless phases of mass incarceration.

In the 1960s and 1970s, the argument for expanding incarceration had a certain reasonable dimension, because the United States had problems with crime—young people have a higher propensity to commit crime, as do antisocial people, and the United States was well supplied with both: Boomers. Crime rose until 1991, after which Boomers had begun to age out of the brackets most liable to commit crimes. (Notably, the large Millennial generation does not seem as disposed to crime as its forbears.) And had Boomers maintained fast economic growth, crime might have fallen without the need for a penal state, as economic growth tends to depress crime, all else being demographically equal.51

Even with these failures, the prison population should have leveled off in the 1990s, instead of growing. The traditional justification for mass imprisonment is deterrence, but on that basis the prison population had reached some efficient peak no later than the early 1990s—subsequent prison growth was costly and ineffective. A survey by the Brennan Center found that prison growth in the 1990s had “relatively little to do with the crime decline,” concluding “that the dramatic increases in incarceration have had a limited, diminishing effect on crime.”52 (An aging population did, however, seem to help from 1990 to 1999; there was no evidence of aging’s effects after 2000, notably.53)

The anti-empirical Boomers, of course, had no patience for analysis: Going forward, it would be “three strikes, you’re out.” It was a perfect system for the nation’s chief judicial officer, Boomer John Roberts, who during his Supreme Court confirmation hearings compared the role of a judge to that of an umpire counting balls and strikes. Given the Boomers’ test scores, it’s helpful strikes were limited to three. America was at least spared the vista of Boomer judges discalcing themselves to add past ten or, God forbid, disrobing entirely to get past twenty.

The 51st State

What’s going on here? This chart shows the total number of Americans either in physical custody or under correctional supervision (probation, parole). The rise in corrections began before the Boomers took power, but there was, at the time, a serious problem with crime (often perpetrated by then-youthful Boomers). By the early 1990s, crime had already plateaued, but thanks to punitive, bipartisan laws, the correctional population just kept growing, at undeniable financial and human cost and without any strong evidence of a deterrent aspect. Only recently has the fraction declined modestly, and quite a bit of that has been driven by a few states like California releasing masses of prisoners, in some instances because prisons were so overcrowded that they violated Constitutional requirements for decent treatment, which counts as a fairly meager improvement. Even correcting for overall population growth, the prison explosion remains—the total correctional population rose from 0.81 percent of the population in 1980 to 2.46 percent in 2007.54

It was the arrival of laws like three-strikes that drove so much imprisonment during the 1990s and 2000s. Even if the need for deterrence had waned, the desire for Levitical justice waxed. The Boomers were fed up with crime, which their own generation had helped drive to high levels, and rather than engage in self-reflection or a detailed study of humane alternatives, opted as usual for the most expedient response—crude and often indiscriminate punishment. Historical discretion for clemency would be progressively removed from the mid-1980s by mandatory sentencing guidelines, the better to ensure that pre-Boomer judges (another detestable elite) would not allow legal knowledge, intimacy with the facts, or human compassion to interfere with the punitive task at hand. Discretion and mercy were further circumscribed when Washington State held a referendum that approved the first modern three-strikes law in 1993, followed over the next two years by twenty-three other states as diverse as California, Louisiana, and Vermont, a situation that proves that even red and blue states could find some toxic common ground under Boomer leadership. There has been some relaxation of these laws since, but not nearly enough.

The relentless prosecution of nonviolent drug and property crimes also padded numbers. Nixon appointed the first drug czar, but the war on substances entered a new phase with the Boomers. One of the first Boomer drug warriors was, appropriately enough, Bill Bennett (Reagan’s second secretary of education), who transitioned along with his students from the school to the justice system, the instantiation in a single person of the Boomers’ school-to-prison pipeline. Didn’t-inhale Bill Clinton also participated, appointing drug czars with a remit to do everything from hunting down doctors advising on medical marijuana to funding aerial dispersals of herbicides to kill coca plants in Colombia, a strategy that recalled the whole scandal over Agent Orange in Vietnam and proved about as effective.55 (Clinton also supported, for some time, a ban on funding needle exchanges as part of the law-and-order spectacle.) The list goes on, including the zero-tolerance policies and “Broken Windows” policing endorsed by New York City’s (Boomer) mayor Rudy Giuliani and practiced by his cogenerational lieutenant at the NYPD, Bill Bratton.

Even as Boomer police forces grew and were given ever stricter mandates to pursue even the most minor crimes (like turnstile jumping, an original object of the NYPD’s zero-tolerance policy), the offices of public defenders were slowly starved of funds. The public defense system, never well funded, needed to at least keep up with the human inventory stockpiled by newly vigorous police departments. Because compensating defense funds were not forthcoming, when prison populations reached a peak in 2007 the nation had the full-time equivalent of just 15,000 conventional public defenders against a caseload of 5.6 million.*,56 How this math allowed the justice system to fulfill its constitutional duty to provide defendants with adequate counsel went unpondered by the Boomers.57

After the 2008 crash, prison populations declined somewhat, the product of a minor transition to leniency, a certain lack of funding after the 2008 crash, and in some cases, court-ordered release of prisoners held in institutions so overcrowded as to violate the Eighth Amendment’s ban on cruel and unusual punishment. It is too soon to tell if the pattern will persist. Certainly, the aging of the Boomer blue-collar criminal class helps, as does the absence of mass detention for white-collar crimes associated with recent stock market crashes.,58

Regardless of the recent and minor dip in prisoners, the United States still has the largest prison population in the world on an absolute basis (despite being a distant third in population; China and India are each four times larger). A quarter of the world’s prisoners reside in US prisons, although less than 5 percent of the world’s population is American.59 Of all major countries, save perhaps Russia, the United States has by far the largest prison population per capita—around 0.7 percent of Americans are in detention (1 in 143) and 2.1 percent in the correctional system in total (including supervised parolees, or 1 in 47).60 These numbers are down from their peak in 2007, almost entirely due to the decrease in probationers, rather than prisoners, and even Obama’s worthy grants of clemency in his final year are a rounding error.61 Many prisoners deserve to be where they are, but many others could have ended up somewhere else had the Boomer system not failed them. Instead, they reside in prisons full to bursting, which is less hyperbole than numerical fact. In 2014 federal facilities were at 128 percent of rated capacity, with states ranging from a low of 50 percent (New Mexico) to a high of 150 percent (Illinois), and combined population averages almost 112 percent of maximum ratings—in other words, the prisons are stuffed.62

Beyond normative issues, this massive prison population is an economic liability. Prisoners produce almost no economic value and are expensive to house (though private prisons have partly offset costs by monetizing inmate labor, a situation uncomfortably close to slavery). A survey of forty states showed each additional prisoner had an official real cost of $31,286.63 In California, the government estimates it cost $47,102 annually to incarcerate a person as of 2009, a price that rose by $19,500 in less than a decade; this trend will continue.64 California is an expensive state for anything, but the federal government, even with the dubious benefit of economies of scale and facilities in cheaper states, has an average inmate cost of $30,620 per year.65 We can debate what an “average” taxpayer is, but given effective tax rates and ranges it would take the entire tax revenue of at least four and up to a dozen middling taxpayers to support a single prisoner—or, to use state analogies again, it would be like taxing Virginia to imprison Nebraska.* Depending on assumptions and tastes, different states could be chosen, but the point is simply that there’s something off about a society that spends so much to achieve so little.

Naturally, the neoliberal machine has offered its services (private prisons) to siphon off public funds to be transferred to their shareholders and Boomer executives. The largest of these private prisons are Corrections Corporation of America and GEO—the first founded by Boomers and the second by a Boomer-age immigrant raised in America and well immersed in Boomer culture. These completed the neoliberal custodial trinity: charter schools, for-profit universities, and now their barbed-wire equivalents, privatized prisons. There are indications that this experiment may be faltering, but with public prisons full, there will be private prisons for some time.

The total costs of the prison state are necessarily large: about $86 billion across federal, state, and local prisons.66 (For context, California’s corrections budget considerably exceeds that state’s grants to the entire UC system.67) Only part of the costs are paid out of current receipts, given the federal deficit, and states’ reliance on long-term debt to pay for prison construction; therefore, many of these costs will be passed down. The biggest cost, perhaps, will arrive when prisoners fulfill their sentences and return to the general population, a process only just beginning. These future parolees include huge subpopulations of the old, the mentally ill, and the badly educated, whose infirmities and convictions preclude them from many jobs. They will therefore be transferred from one form of state-subsidized living to another: welfare, Medicaid, etc.68

The American justice system has always had its biases, against minorities and the poor, and these are not the Boomers’ creations. What Boomers are responsible for is the explosion in the prison population, vastly increasing the numbers of those exposed to institutional injustice while providing no real path for these prisoners to become self-sufficient on release. As ex-convicts bleed into the probation system and then the general public, the costs will be disproportionately borne by current and future taxpayers, not the Boomers who presided over mass incarceration in the first place.

One notable perversity of Boomer justice is the creation of a police state by Leftists of the very same generation so heavily associated with protesting the “pigs” during the Vietnam War, the 1968 Democratic Convention, and so on, their supposedly libertarian cogenerationalists, and even small-state Rightists. Ideological consistency proved no restraint, and the Boomers sanctioned the police to be the sword and arm of newly discovered middle-class moralism. What changed? Now, it was not peace symbols being spray-painted on public buildings, but crimes against Boomer properties. The junkies were no longer the (whitish) denizens of 1967’s Love Fest, but people of discomfiting hues despoiling dog parks and other conveniences required by the Boomers. Blacks for whom the Boomers had supposedly rallied in the 1960s were swept into prison at rates vastly greater than the whites, with black men 3.8 to 10.5 times more likely to be serving a year or more than comparable whites, depending on age.69

The Brennan Center noted that an “aging population” contributed somewhat to the decline in crime. Young people historically have a greater propensity to commit crime, but the arrival of the very large Millennial generation prompted no crime wave, nor was there anything comparable before the 1960s. The Boomers may be more entangled than anyone realized. After all, something changed from 1967 to 1991, and we will pay the price for decades to come. Alas, the Boomer decades have left the country ill equipped to pay for anything, including a spectacularly ill-advised prison state.

CHAPTER SEVENTEEN

PRICE TAGS AND PRESCRIPTIONS

Behold, I was shapen in iniquity; and in
sin did my mother conceive me.

—Psalm 51:51

When the original Bad Parents, Adam and Eve, took the serpent’s advice over God’s, they lost the family home (Eden) and gained an enduring legacy (original sin). The Old Testament does not explicitly record how the first children, Cain and Abel, reconciled themselves to this dismal inheritance, though we can infer from the subsequent fratricide that the family’s reduced circumstances produced some tensions. To our post-Freudian eyes, Cain’s murder of Abel seems like classic displacement; surely, there were more obvious targets. But Adam and Eve endured (the former for 930 years), snakes multiplied, and the celestial grandfather hung around until Nietzsche killed finally him off circa 1882. Laboring under the burden of their progenitors’ sin, succeeding generations had a rougher go. The rest of the Old Testament reads like the files from a psychiatric hospital, filled with murder, revenge, theft, and war, to say nothing about the really unsettling bits like the tales of Lot and his daughters. Despite engendering this whole mess, Adam and Eve eventually trended heavenward, an ideal vantage point from which to view their offspring’s descent to less hospitable climes.

Coping with the legacies left by bad parents is an eternal challenge, in which grace and fairness rarely feature. The millions of Americans who will shortly partake of this ancient drama, individually and as a society, should do so with care. The temptation will be to frustration, and the danger, that frustration will be misdirected: toward siblings, spouses, nurses, estate lawyers, Medicare bureaucrats, and everyone else tasked with taking care of people who didn’t take care of themselves—i.e., at society, instead of at the sociopaths. Misdirected squabbling would suit the Boomers, since it would distract the young from pursuing the real culprits. The Boomers should not be granted that satisfaction.

Instead, we should remember who caused the problems in the first place and do as a society what decent people do individually with their own cranky, aging, and culpable parents. The first step is to appreciate when the elderly are no longer competent and to remove from them the ability to harm self or others, or run up any more debts. That accomplished, you can tabulate the mistakes: the second mortgages, inadequate insurance, accumulating doctors’ bills, leaky roofs, the lot of it. You then, the estate planners tell us, liquidate what parental assets there are to meet those obligations and the additional costs of long-term care. Any shortfalls will be your obligation, one way or another.

Many of those who have already been through this saga know that no real gratitude will be forthcoming. At best, these good deeds will be viewed as nothing less than your duty, and at worst, the elderly will let fly accusations of churlishness and ingratitude. This will be infuriating, especially considering that any money you spend will come from a paycheck depleted by various deductions for senior programs you may never fully enjoy, even as those deductions supply Social Security checks that parents brandish as proof of their self-sufficiency. The mechanisms of a national, sociopathic agenda subverts Tolstoy: Each family can now be unhappy in the same way, and multiplying the above frustrations by 75 million, the remaining Boomer population, equals a lot of unhappiness and more than a little rage. Whether these feelings can be channeled into a productive coalition instead of fratricidal conflict over collateral issues, is this book’s final subject.

If the Boomers can be removed from power, then the tallying and division of liabilities can begin. Alas, America cannot rely on a refreshing fiscal baptism to remit sin, even though this is essentially what Candidate Trump proposed, through his unprecedented suggestion of national default. Nor can America force Boomers into the confessional in the hopes that the bridges, schools, and the prison-state repair themselves after a sufficient number of Hail Marys, or their political equivalent, the hollow apologies of the politician caught out. There will be no moment of grace, no great catharsis, only a succession of checks written and budgets reallocated. It is a process not without a quiet nobility. It also has its cold satisfactions, including the collection of funds from the Boomers themselves.

Remediating the sociopathic Superfund site of Boomer America will be expensive. In money alone, the project will require $8.65 trillion soon and over $1 trillion in additional annual investment. Given the past chapters, the size of the bill will not come as complete shock. What may be surprising is that the United States can afford all of it.

Though dormant for many decades, the argument for investment remains as powerful and straightforward as ever: Proper investment enriches society over the long run. Good as this is, there is no getting around one frustrating reality, which is that the size of the tab and the age of its originators are considerable, so that those doing most of the paying will be the least culpable. It’s plausible that the youngest Americans will eventually receive a decent return on their investment. If they are forward thinking, it shouldn’t be difficult to convince them to support the necessary reforms. The harder task is to persuade middle-aged Americans, who will succeed the Boomers in power, to pursue costly change. By virtue of their age, Americans in midlife have substantial incomes, making them prime targets for new taxation, while also being sufficiently old to make full recoupment unlikely. These Americans (mostly GenX but also including the youngest Boomers of the nonsociopathic variety) will need to be motivated by patriotism and the interests of their own children. They will be called upon to do much, and they deserve an honest treatment of what needs to be fixed and how much that will really cost. There can be no more Laffer Curves, free-lunch privatization schemes, or any of the other delusional neoliberal theology that offers salvation without good works.

As to those good works, they are legion and expensive. While the totals are necessarily imprecise and debatable, the bill’s general enormity is undeniable. Whether the sum is $6, $8.65, or $10+ trillion, it’s always trillions and always many of them. Collecting all the strands covered before, the next table shows the rough tab, excluding the $18+ trillion in national debt about which we can and should do nothing immediate.

The Bill

Infrastructure

Near-Term Costs: $3.6 trillion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $100 billion

Pensions

Near-Term Costs: $1 trillion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $200 billion

Military

Near-Term Costs: $800 billion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $100 billion

Entitlements/Health Care

Near-Term Costs: $750 billion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $200 billion

Climate

Near-Term Costs: $1 trillion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $150 billion

Education/R&D

Near-Term Costs: $1.5 trillion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $250 billion

Extra interest

Near-Term Costs: —

Ongoing Additional Costs: $170 billion (minimum)

Total

Near-Term Costs: $8.65 trillion

Ongoing Additional Costs: $1.17 trillion

Note: “Near-term” means the next few years, a window that reflects both the cheapest time to remediate and also the period in which part of the sum can be collected from the Boomers; it is for those reasons more front-loaded than it could otherwise be. “Ongoing” simply means the additional, unbudgeted expense over the next thirty or so years, at which point certain items like education, pensions, and climate should be in good enough shape that they can be maintained fairly cheaply and we can finally begin repaying part of the national debt.

These are the rough prices to keep the system going the way it is, and we may decide that these are unacceptably high prices to pay for certain items. But we have to choose, not just let the system drift along, spawning deficits to uncertain purpose. Significant reductions to entitlement programs, limiting foreign intervention, reducing spending in thinly populated areas—all items to consider—would greatly reduce the total. Keep in mind that TARP alone, designed to clean up the financial mess of 2008, was authorized to expend/invest up to $700 billion just on the financial sector and could have been a complete loss (in the end, it was not). A slightly larger sum for ongoing investment, instead of crisis management, does not seem undue in that context. Certainly, it would help if the government passed along a digestable summary of its financial position to taxpayers—it supplies projected benefits information, which is about as complicated and political a figure as one can imagine, to Social Security contributors. Could goverment not also provide, with a receipt for every annual tax filing, a one-page statement of the government’s financial position and the use of monies? This might assist taxpayers in deciding what they really want to fund, allowing for a degree of informed consent.

Even slimmed-down, some parts of this agenda cannot be easily avoided—major spending on infastructure, R&D, and some welfare seems like a precondition to a growing, functional society and these alone will cost trillions. Investments at this scale demand sacrifice, not a favorite Boomer word. These are sums associated with major wars, and they demand commensurate effort, meaning higher taxes, more investment, and less profligacy. Collecting the money requires exquisite care, since sloppy tax hikes can punish growth, and the whole point is to return America to a trajectory of quick upward growth.* That rules out the cruder mechanisms of austerity in the Teutonic mold (practiced recently, and to devastating effect, by Berlin on Athens) and the self-limiting let-the-rich-pay-it-all populism of the extreme Left and Right.

What could work is an investment program, much of it administered by the state, initially funded by debt and ultimately paid for by moderate tax increases on most Americans. After years of neoliberal conditioning, such a program may seem irretrievably Leftist, fundamentally un-American, or antithetical to growth; none of these descriptions are warranted. All of these strategies have been pursued before, often quite successfully, and by both parties. Using tax revenues to support even the most expensive and state-centered programs, e.g., infrastructure and defense, would not strike a 1950s Republican like Dwight Eisenhower as creeping socialism, for the simple reason that he did so himself. Doubtless, some of this book’s proposals are to the notional Left of Obama and Clinton; then again, those politicians offered policies that frequently lay to the Right of Nixon, except in certain matters of civil rights. It’s all a matter of perspective, and that perspective should be supplied by data and social consensus, not the idiosyncratic worldview of the shrinking Boomer electorate.

The Boomer mess is the largest challenge the nation has faced in some time, though once the Boomer establishment has been replaced, it will be helpful to view reform as a process of manageable fiscal adjustments, instead of an opportunity to avenge a cosmic injustice. The Boomers might deserve to bear almost all of the burden, but as a practical matter, they cannot. Everyone will have to participate, though to the extent Boomers can be targeted without ruining them, they should be.

The Easy(ish) Part: Borrowing and Investing

After so many chapters skewering the Boomers for their addiction to debt, it may seem odd to call for more borrowing, though more borrowing is the appropriate course. No level of taxation can provide enough immediate funds, and borrowing is unusually cheap in the post-2008 world. The difference between the borrowing of the Boomer years and the borrowing of the future rests in how funds are used. The old practice of subsidizing transient consumption with perpetual debt needs to go. The way forward must be tax and invest, not tax and spend, and new debt should be viewed as an instrument to deal with a temporary difficulty, to be reduced when the challenge abates.

Distinguishing between investment and consumption is a subject treated at length in policy literature and worthy of considerable pondering by bureaucrats, but no voter has time or opportunity to do the same. When bond issuances arrive on the ballot, the options are “yes” and “no.” To resolve that binary in the three minutes allotted in the voting booth, a rule of thumb helps: if a project does not provide benefits for at least as long as the term of the associated debt, that project should be viewed with (nondispositive) suspicion. Projects with fleeting and unquantifiable benefits are likely to be disguised consumption. It should also (though it hasn’t, for thirty-odd years) go without saying that total ascertainable benefits should exceed total costs.* These are not rules to be applied with unthinking narrowness. Some worthy projects are inherently speculative and may seem to fall outside the rubric, like California’s 2004 proposal to fund stem cell research. At the time, it was not clear when or if the state’s $3 billion investment would be recouped. In the end, California voted “yes” and that was the right choice, both ex ante and post hoc. Moreover, while any specific R&D project might be speculative, in the aggregate, R&D has a long history of positive and enduring returns. A little perspective is all that’s required to make these rules functional guides to the profusion of bond requests made of voters. Olympic stadium: out. Decent schools: in.

When good projects do arrive, even debt-obsessed voters should not (for now) be deterred by the scope of obligations incurred. American interest rates are near zero in real terms and the arrival of subzero returns on Japanese and European sovereign debt will limit the upward pressure on rates that huge new debts usually entail. The world has vast amounts of cash looking for a positive yield and very few good places to find it: Swiss banks in 2015–2016 actually charged major depositors for the privilege of holding ready funds. In such a world, America can offer rates that are both absolutely low and extremely competitive, perhaps 1–2 percent, eminently affordable even to a highly indebted nation. This happy climate is not guaranteed to last, any more than rotting bridges are guaranteed to stand absent repair.

This brings us to infrastructure, sorely in need of investment, in everything from filling potholes to upgrading systems like Amtrak’s increasingly rickety Northeast Corridor, which also happens to be by far the most profitable and rational part of the Amtrak system, though it has the misfortune of serving urban corridors that rural congressmen despise.2 Bridges to nowhere and vanity projects have given infrastructure a bad reputation. But making sensible, data-driven investments provides safety, profit, and new jobs. If doing so benefits the coasts (and it will), so be it; they pay the taxes anyway.* Given systemic underemployment, infrastructure investment will provide jobs without much upward pressure on wages. One could easily envision spending $3–4 trillion in the next few years, reaping a net benefit and little inflationary damage. It’s a substantial investment—an order of magnitude more than anything proposed during the 2016 election—but anything meaningfully less will do equally little good.

Given the unusually good environment for issuing government bonds, it is also a good time to relieve student debt. Government borrows much more cheaply than students and may as well use its advantage by assuming many student debts directly—including the $150 billion owed to private parties as of 2012 (the date of the latest comprehensive data).3 Many loans are already “impaired,” and the government is already in the forgiveness business through front-end mechanisms like means-tested repayments, deferrals, and outright forbearances (i.e., write-offs). On the back end, the government is on the hook through guarantees and automatic programs like welfare and other safety net entitlements. So it is really just a question of timing, costs, and allocation, the sorts of arbitrage and fiddling Wall Street loves in other contexts; we just have to be honest about the mechanics.

The gains of forgiveness would be substantial, emotionally (student borrowers are “distressed” in various senses) and fiscally. Federal student loans carried an interest rate in 2015–2016 of between 4.3 and 6.8 percent, with private loans carrying higher rates, to say nothing of the even higher costs of credit extended to cover student living expenses.4 By contrast, the ten-year Treasury yield was, in mid-2016, about 1.8 percent. If only half of student debt were retired, this interest rate arbitrage would save $20–30 billion annually. Any savings are, of course, from the student (and, long-term, social) perspective; the various and often predatory corporations who issue or hold these loans would be deprived of an equal sum (and the Treasury of some revenues, though by relieving students of some debt, the government might help students live more productive lives and eventually generate more tax revenue). Rationalizing student loans could also shore up the financial system, since many private loan holders have shaky finances—this was a problem in the 2000s for Sallie Mae, the sort-of-private-sort-of-public loan provider—and dealing with systemic problems early is invariably cheaper than cleaning them up during a crisis. No one should be deluded that this is anything other than a bailout, and one with very distasteful aspects, subsidizing some very bad decisions by students and helping out some dubious participants in the loan business. That is the dirty nature of all responses to financial crises. Better the government address these problems now, before crushing debt derails younger lives prematurely and the costs arrive, compounded, via the back doors of welfare and other programs. Student debt is just one example of the flexibility permitted by the currently low costs of government borrowing.

In a less sociopathic political environment, even America’s largest programs can be fixed fairly easily with minor adjustments, entirely affordable relative to the giant consequences of inaction. Returning Social Security to long-term balance requires moderate increases to FICA taxes and minor increases of the retirement age to reflect increased longevity (Chapter 12). Climate policy needs appropriate investments in energy infrastructure and R&D and reforms like cap-and-trade, which are not terribly expensive in the short-term and bring long-term benefits to public and private parties. The cap-and-trade programs implemented to deal with acid rain in the 1990s provoked no recessions and California, which has had its own carbon cap-and-trade program in effect since 2012–2013, is prosperous. Any temporary dislocations would be small compared to both the total economy and the damage averted. Even the military can be brought back to full readiness in just a few years at fairly modest cost by undoing the arbitrary damage of sequestration and culling the self-serving fauna of congressional pork and white-elephant systems.

Because debt is presently so cheap and many of the largest challenges like Social Security and climate have costs that can be spread over many years, some of the largest problems are actually the easiest to address, conceptually, if not politically. The real challenge is equitably allocating the various costs and avoiding the waste that attends any large reshuffling of funds.

The Harder Adjustments: Healthy Debt, Tax Increases, Benefit Cuts, and Avoiding Waste

Except in severe recessions, any additions to the debt should be accompanied by budgets that pay current interest out of current revenues and come with reasonable plans for their eventual extinguishment.* Investing $8.65 trillion immediately would add considerably to nominal interest payments, though because real interest rates are near zero, even borrowing at this scale carries modest costs. Still, even nominal obligations must be paid and interest plus ongoing investments would add about $1.2 trillion in spending, and that means new taxes.

Total tax receipts in the United States are close to $7 trillion across federal, state, and local, taxes, so meeting new expenses implies a relative tax increase of 21–25 percent, substantial but not unbearable. To allay any heart attacks, that means the highest nominal federal rates might rise to around 50 percent (from 39.6 percent, though the effective rates would be much lower). For average taxpayers, their effective 15 percent rate would creep up to 18 percent or slightly higher. These figures assume the current tax and benefits systems otherwise stay the same, which, just to calm down the Rightist reader, they palpably should not. We can and should rejigger the brackets, FICA allocations, benefits, deductions, and so forth. Pulling a few of the tax codes’ many levers might leave new tax rates much closer to current rack rates, raising revenue while eliminating the distorting subsidies embedded in the code. It’s possible to be fiscally prudent without dismantling the government or flirting with confiscatory taxation, though no one should be deluded that the total tax take must go up, starting with taxes on the Boomers. (It seems impossible that this will happen in 2017, but the elections of 2018 and 2020 offer new opportunities.)

Seniors—i.e., Boomers—will view higher taxes as an unfairness not to be borne and the prospect of reduced benefits as an outrage; anyway, they will argue, they don’t have the money. Like much of Boomer dialogue, such assertions are mostly self-serving and false. The Boomers did not pay their fair share of taxes, as the national debt and general decay attest, and Boomers should make good on their debts. As for pensions, benefits, and other senior citizen bonuses, the Boomers might argue that they are at the end of their working lives and so any cuts would be an unprecedented cruelty.* Well, it might be an inconvenience, but it would not be a cruelty, morally or fiscally, and certainly not unprecedented. The moral facts have been established. So have the fiscal facts: Older people do have a lot to tax. The richer ones own a disproportionate amount of wealth, much of which generates income whether the Boomers are working or not. Even less rich seniors receive all manner of benefits, pensions, and other overly generous/unsustainable payments that can be reduced either directly or through the tax, whether or not they have considerable money assets (and many do not). Some age-targeted taxes may be unconstitutional and others, however legal, may be effectively quashed by stalling litigation that allows the Boomers to make it to the grave untouched. However, the very Boomer policies designed to protect their generational interests also create many unambiguously legal and fair targets, correlated with age and ripe for harvest.

Social Security is the obvious place to start, and the retirement age should be raised for anyone reasonably able to work, including the younger Boomers, by at least three years. (“Early” retirement would then happen at sixty-five, and “full” retirement at seventy or later.) Similar revisions were made in 1983, in a way that protected the Boomers (Chapter 12). It’s time to do it again, without generational indulgence. Wealthier Boomers can also have their benefits taxed more aggressively, another strategy backed by precedent. Clawing back old-age benefits has the advantage of being generationally targeted and also sends a message to younger workers that the state cannot (and indeed, never intended to nor did) cover all of retirement. Northern Europeans have vastly more generous welfare states and higher personal savings rates; they understand that even in generous systems, individual responsibility remains paramount.

There are other areas where taxes can be reasonably, generationally targeted. The Boomers are the cohort presently reaping the greatest gains from inheritances, and these can be taxed at something above the functionally zero rate that generally applies. Indeed, doing so would be downright republican (lowercase), given that low inheritance taxes are oddities in a nation founded, however glancingly, in opposition to inherited privilege. The exemption, now at $5.45 million, can be lowered dramatically, allowing sentimental items to be passed along without abetting dynastic wealth while shoring up the fisc. Other exemptions can be reduced or abolished, including the “step-up” basis at death, a loophole that directs the IRS to exclude any qualifying gains that accrued during a giver’s lifetime, which can be most of them.* When Britain decided its parasitic and antidemocratic gentry needed to go, the mechanism was “death duties.” That was a century ago; certainly twenty-first-century America can be at least as progressive as Edwardian Britain. Why, precisely, do the senior viewers of PBS care so much about how Downton Abbey will survive the predations of Lloyd George and his death duties? Because Boomers have their own McDowntons to worry about.

Even before they change hands, American McDowntons are already protected by some generationally discriminatory exemptions that themselves deserve revision, especially the property tax caps enacted since the 1970s. The Boomers have long profited from these anomalies at the expense of schools, infrastructure, and the residential aspirations of younger Americans. The longer one stays put, the more valuable the cap becomes—caps assume that the taxable value of property increases at an arbitrarily low rate, say 2 percent, even if in many markets appreciation is much higher. So a long-term resident in Malibu might be taxed as if his home were worth $1 million, even if an identical property next door just sold for $25 million and is taxed accordingly. Revising these caps would be progressive, both in standard terms and generational ones. It would also be efficient, as caps distort all sorts of economic decision making, reducing labor market flexibility by encouraging people to stay put, which makes no sense in an era where lifetime employment has vanished and jobs migrate. (The same is true of rent control, another strategy that favors seniors while constraining supply and forcing the price of unrestricted rentals upward.) The usual counterargument is that such revisions will displace seniors who cannot afford to live in the homes of their choice, to which the answer is: tough. The law confers rights of citizenship in the United States, not a right to reside in a particular place. Abolishing caps and rent control may create short-term price declines, though this would serve as something of a generational equalizer, putting more homes in reach of younger cohorts, among whom rates of homeownership are notably depressed.

Vast as the generational subsidies of property tax protections are, they pale in comparison to medical spending, consumed by seniors in disproportionate amount and substantially at public expense—a fact the simple existence of Medicare’s age-qualification underlines. The most reasonable reforms entail more cost-benefit analyses of the sort routinely imposed on other government programs; rationing, to use the charged term. Evangelical Republicans may not care for “death panels,” but who are they to defy their God, who sayeth that the “days of our years are threescore years and ten” or, at most, by “reason of strength” (or Medicare) might extend to “fourscore”?5 Let us grant the evangelical wish that Washington cease interfering with God’s design, at least on this matter. Anyway, social programs are supposed to do the greatest social good, not cater to false sentiments about kindly geriatrics. Costly interventions to drag a life out a few unproductive months, at the price of a lost generation of children, do not balance in the Benthamite books. If they were true to their principles, instead of bowing to Boomer hypocrisy, both the Left and the Right would each find something to like about rationing.

The prospect of rationing may also encourage the Boomers to embrace more sensible medical policies. It would expose neoliberal welfare as the unviable chimera it is, a policy that simultaneously requires the government be the single largest buyer of health care while forbidding the state from using its market power to negotiate discounts from the medical oligopolies the Boomers helped create. More thoughtful policies can save a lot, while sacrificing little. Sweden spends 9.6 percent of GDP on health versus America’s 16.9 percent (in 2012), and Stockholm isn’t exactly littered with the corpses of neglected seniors.6

Rich as many Boomers are, many are not, and this means generational taxation alone can never suffice. Taxes will need to rise generally, even on the sacred cow of the middle class, whose teats have been supposedly abused but have actually experienced only the most tender caresses. Nowhere, in the great debates over the progressivity of the American tax system that have raged for years, has there ever been real discussion of asking anything of the middle class. All major candidates in 2016 promised relief for “middle-class” taxpayers, a now-customary ritual. Why the middle class should get a break has never been clearly articulated, for the same reason that the definition of “middle class” is never articulated. The vast majority of the electorate (up to 87 percent) views themselves as some sort of “middle class” and therefore interprets any proposed breaks to be in their immediate self-interest.7 This is one promise Boomer politicians usually keep, and it has shielded the vast middle from paying its fair share.

Before we get to the middle, let’s start with the sins of the bottom and top, the respective fixations of the Right and Left. The bottom quintile or so already receives net subsidies from the government, and these transfers seem like something of a precondition to a functioning society in practice, regardless of their theoretical merits. Presently they seem set to a level that is, roughly, minimally functional, so there is little to trim—the subsidies are small enough that meaningful reductions would create mass unrest without much fiscal gain. Not even the Kochs want to risk repeating Louis XVI’s flight to Varennes (or Zurich, at any rate) and there’s little we can do here. The lower-middle class, however, does have something to contribute—it is taxed at exceedingly low rates, so that many of its members pay less than they receive in benefits. Nor is the lower-middle some citadel of unalloyed virtue. While the evasions of the upper brackets feature more zeroes, the less wealthy commit their own evasions. Cash-based compensation, like tips and so on, frequently go unreported. Swan in to an upscale hair salon, past the doors proudly announcing the acceptance of Visa and Amex, and you see an ATM, there to dispense untraceable cash for tips, testaments to the culture of low-stakes evasion. The IRS gives this sort of cheating a free pass, because it lacks resources to take action. Aside from examining suspicious returns reporting zero income, the IRS basically does not scrutinize the “middle class” at all: It examines 0.5 percent of filers reporting incomes between $25,000 and $200,000, while it examines 6 percent, 10 percent, and 16 percent of returns reporting incomes over $1, $5, and $10 million, respectively.8 All parts of the middle class can contribute somewhat more, and the IRS can ensure that they do.

As for soaking the rich, there aren’t that many of them, and they can be dunked only so many times. Even dramatic tax hikes on this small population would produce at most an extra $300 to $400 billion, which does not completely close current deficits, to say nothing of the additional investments called for.* Nor would abolishing favorable rates on capital gains and dividends be sufficient, supplying perhaps $200 billion annually, and only if the market holds together.9 (The amount is notably low because so many capital gains are shielded by middle-class retirement plans.) The wealthy should pay their share, but they already pay quite a lot: the top quintile of earners (households earning an average of about $270,000 annually) paid 69.0 percent of federal income taxes; the top 1 percent alone pay 25.4 percent of taxes.10 Respectively, these groups account for 52.6 and 15.0 percent of income; they pay more relative to their share of income and other groups pay less, which is precisely the point of the progressive system and the existence of a skew itself is not a critique of the social policies of a progressive system. Whatever your position about the fairness of how the rich generate their income, there’s no getting around the heavy dependence of the government on receipts from a very small number of people, and the implications of this have not been much discussed outside of some (self-serving and overheated) Rightist think tanks.

While progressivity is important, the point many have missed is that excessive focus on collections from just the richest risks further social distortions, from the perspectives of the Left, Right, and what remains of the center. Populists should keep in mind that a system that is already disproportionately funded by the rich will become ever more captive to them as taxes increase. The rich will become even more interested in tax policy, while the government will become ever more dependent on the well-being of a tiny class of individuals and cater to them accordingly; if you have only one goose laying golden eggs, the goose had better be happy. Overtaxing the rich also encourages other unhealthy dynamics. Those who pay tend to feel they own; those who do not cannot feel quite the same. After a certain point, extreme progressivity defeats the social purpose it seeks to achieve, reducing society to oligarchy versus mob, with the oligarchy feeling entitled to govern at whim and emotionally justified in evading a burden others do not really share.*,11 The mob, lacking a sense of proprietorship, can hardly be expected to take a proper interest in maintaining society—how much can a person who pays no net taxes really complain about what the government is doing with his “tax dollars”? The tax system should be progressive and perhaps highly so, not utterly lopsided.

Taxes on almost the entire base should rise and levies should be more efficiently collected. The IRS can receive proper funding to collect what people fail to pay. The Service estimates that at least $450 billion goes uncollected every year, and even after audits, more than $400 billion that is owed will never be collected.12 Proper funding of the Service could retrieve a significant fraction of the deficit by itself, about as much as a major hike on the rich would, without changing a single rate. It is not enough by itself, but it would help, and it would be equitable.

Similar reforms of corporate taxation would provide additional revenue, while keeping things fair and improving American competitiveness. Official (rather than effective) American corporate tax rates are high by global standards, which encourages evasion, of more and less legal means. Large, sophisticated and aggressive corporations, like Apple and GE, have often paid nothing.13 (It used to be joked that GE was, by attorneys employed, the largest tax law firm in the world; that’s not the highest and best use of GE’s resources.) Lower and more uniform taxation would be more fair to smaller corporations and encourage larger companies to remain in America, instead of being “domiciled” in micronations that have nothing to do with a company’s core business.

Higher taxes would impact consumption, though this is not necessarily bad, especially if consumption taxes helped reflect the real cost of purchases, many of which are subsidized by society (meaning: younger generations). Though consumption taxes have long enjoyed support in policy circles, they are frequently derided as political nonstarters, which is bizarre as many such taxes already exist: sales taxes, regulatory fees like car registration taxes, gas taxes, use taxes, tolls, and even property taxes, capped as they are. Even if consumption taxes of the kind seen in Europe are impracticable, raising existing consumption taxes would not only generate revenue and encourage savings, it would help internalize externalities, i.e., the true social costs of the goods consumed. The anomalously low price of energy in America fails to capture the total costs fossil fuels create, and a simple way to reduce emissions is to raise the price of fuel. As fuel has been relatively cheap for a few years, it is a convenient time to raise taxes on fuel. Some may protest that consumption taxes, or even carbon taxes, are unfairly regressive, but they are small components of a generally progressive tax system and also the most direct means of making consumers bear the real cost of their purchases.

Along the same lines—of making people assume directly costs that would otherwise be socialized—are insurance fees. The premiums that regulators charge the financial sector, for example, have been inadequate, which was why Congress had to cough up a few hundred billion to rescue the banks in 2008. Social insurance premiums for entitlements, as we’ve seen, are also too low. So are premiums for the semiprivate world of pensions, as the hopeless state of the PBGC shows. Unlike the financial sector, pensions and the PBGC are in sufficiently bad shape that prospective insurance will never be enough to meet existing liabilities. Subsidies will be required from general revenues, as will steep benefits cuts—which the Boomers deeply oppose and must be forced to bear. Again, Social Security and pensions are not promises made by the US Constitution, and anyone who relies exclusively on these programs does so at his peril.*,14 Pensioners should have known better, and a contrary conclusion implies a paternalistic state of breathtaking scale.

The point of trudging up and down the tax tables is to show that there is no one tax revision that can solve the problem by itself. Only taxation on almost the whole tax base, with special emphasis on the Boomers and the properties they control, can supply revenue on the order required (and do so with any fairness). When politicians say that the wealthy are not paying enough taxes, they are right if only because no one is presently paying enough taxes. When politicians say the middle class (whatever that is) pays too much, they ignore both the history and the math. The effective income tax rate for most Americans runs around 15 percent, as we saw in Chapter 8. The bottom fifth receives outright subsidies, and something like 40 to 60 percent of Americans consume, via tax credits, entitlements, and other public services, more economic value than they pay in taxes.15 What politicians are really talking about for the bottom half of the middle class is not tax relief, but deepening the tax subsidy from the wealthy to the lower-middle class. Society can do this, but it should be honest about what is going on, and that will entail dispatching all the nostrums of lower-middle-class virtue from political dialogue. The trade of self-regard for a 3 percent gross tax savings doesn’t seem like the sort of exchange a healthy republic should make.

Every interest group in the world has plans to reform taxes, and no one person can understand the millions of words of federal, state, local, and agency taxes and fees, or the various glosses on them provided by the lobbying industry. No one person—no one voter or reader—has to. All that has to be appreciated is that the scale of the problem defies any cheap fix and that essentially all taxes must rise for some time. My personal hope would be for the state to recede from its role as manager of perpetual financial crisis, concentrating instead on effective regulation and limiting itself to the various things it does best, like building roads, and schools, and funding basic research, with taxes scaled down to lowest reasonable need. After we repair damage to the system, we should consider a return to lower taxes. That point is many years away.

This book started with an analogy of a trial and now that a verdict has been reached (or anyway, the prosecution is resting), the time has come to ask for penalties. In doing so, it’s helpful to revisit the legal framework. In legal terms, what the Boomers did to the country was knowing and voluntary, sometimes reckless but often intentional, and they profited from their actions. This is what the law requires before ordering restitution. While not all of the Boomers directly participated, almost all benefited; they are, as the law would have it, jointly and severally liable. Traditionally, it’s up to group defendants to sort out who should pay what, but in this case the analysis simply collapses to a question of who can pay at all. And given the size of the claim, essentially every Boomer who can pay should. Then again, given the sum involved, so must we all. That is the nature of society, sociopaths be damned.

Avoiding a Repeat: Future Generations

All of these reforms and investments would be of limited utility if another generation of sociopaths emerged. It is not enough to undo the damage; we must avoid a repeat. This is one of the few areas where America can enjoy relatively easy optimism. For better or worse, many of the unique conditions that twisted the Boomers into generational sociopathy will not recur. The comfortable world described in the first two chapters, with its assumptions about effortless future prosperity, has vanished.16 The historical anomaly of bottle-feeding largely disappeared by the mid-1970s (except among the poor). Permissive parenting soldiers on, though plenty of alternative models have arisen to hopefully better effect. Even television, still omnipresent and corrosive, now competes with other diversions that seem less warping. While there are some indications that newer technologies like social networking foster narcissism among the young, and perpetuate the sort of media group-think that prevailed after the abolition of the Fairness Doctrine, nothing quite as bad as television seems to have arrived, though it will be years before we can reach a definitive conclusion. For now, newer technologies do not seem to promote sociopathy in the same way as TV; there has been no Facebook crime wave, or Twitter rampage. (Sometimes hermetic recirculators of misinformation, these platforms allow for crowing and disingenuousness but do not seem to create sociopathic or criminal mind-sets in the first place, with the possible exception of extreme bullying.) As for controversial foreign entanglements, there have been plenty, but the rise of a volunteer army, albeit one distastefully supplemented by mercenaries and black sites, has avoided some of the problems with the draft, problems that anyway seem to have been as much a means to express sociopathic tendencies as a creator of them.

The most important task, if we want to avoid creating another generation of sociopaths, is providing an education in the value society produces and the thoughtful management of personal choices. It is a shame that civics disappeared from the curriculum and that courses on financial literacy never really existed. It is also a tragedy that many view life as a zero-sum game, where wealth can never be created, only reallocated. However disappointing growth has been under the Boomers, the economy has still expanded. These are not the neo–Dark Ages, where the only way to get ahead is for hedge fund managers to practice rapine and plunder on neighboring Westchester villages, though the Boomers seem to believe as much. Naïve as it may sound, inoculating society against the antisocial requires, at bottom, persuading people of what is palpably true: that society has value and everyone should contribute.

A NOTE ON THE NUMBERS AND CONVENTIONS

The goals in presenting data in this book are to be reliable, fair, and clear. Clarity is not always a goal harmonious with the other objectives, and so certain complexities have been placed in the footnotes and endnotes to improve readability. The rest of these notes are not essential for understanding anything in the text—I present them for completeness and because many of the topics discussed are complex, controversial, and the subject of surprisingly… vigorous… academic discussion. (Many think that Picketty and Saez are the last word on income inequality, and while they have done good work, that work is highly controversial—not just in its conclusions, but in its methodologies and data selected.)

Figures presented in this book may also vary from figures cited in the daily news; the latter are often not annualized, not inflation adjusted, and not final—this is no criticism of newspapers, which operate on a different time scale. The following explains why some of these differences appear and why this book’s versions should be more reliable and fair.

For historical comparisons, dollar figures have usually been inflation adjusted with nominal figures shown where relevant. Doing so allows sensible comparisons when long periods are discussed. Readers will not need to understand the adjustment mechanism beyond knowing that $1 in 1980 bought more than $1 does today and that this dynamic has been accounted for. Most dollar figures, except when noted as “nominal,” are presented in 2015 dollars. There has been very little inflation between 2015 and press date, and 2016 figures were not finalized as of the original press date; however, inflation has been subdued for a long time and most 2015 dollar figures will be close in value to current dollars. In cases where data are presented for after October 2016, they are based on projections (usually the government’s) using a source’s estimates and “business as usual” scenarios unless otherwise noted. “Now” and “current” in this book refer to the book’s original press date, though figures remain substantively current.

Historical data are also generally presented end-of-period, not intrayear, except where absolute highs and lows are relevant. Where there are multiple sources, consensus values from the most dependable sources (usually, the government) are presented; consistency has been sought in methods of inflation adjustment where possible, though the government itself uses various metrics for inflation adjustment, like constant and chained dollars. In cases of conflicting sources, priority is generally given to reliable, conservative sources (where “conservative” means the numbers least supportive of the book’s argument). There have also been places where the government has only collected continuous, comparable data over particular periods—for example, for certain items of income, between 1979 and the present. Starting dates and end dates have an effect on magnitudes of change, but for the topics covered do not affect the general directions or conclusions.

Because government frequently revises recent data, there may be some minor deviations between the most recent data presented in the book and the final data released after the book’s original press date. Readers should also be aware that the government’s fiscal year does not match the calendar year and that laws passed in a given year may not be effective until later years; these distinctions are noted when relevant. The government also takes some time to analyze data, and there is usually a multiyear lag for important data, like tax receipts. There can also be quirks in annual accounting—for example, budget deficits can actually vary on the order of $50 billion by virtue of whether the government’s fiscal year ends on a workday or a weekend. Again, most of the data presented are long-term, greatly reducing the importance of these quirks. Different parts of the government produce different analyses of statistics that go under the same term (like “income”) but which embody different concepts. The BEA and the Census, for example, differ substantially on the definition of income and they present figures that are often notably different. I have tried to use consistent sources for the same concepts wherever possible. The trends and conclusions remain the same, because the differences in methodologies tend to produce roughly the same gaps over reasonable periods, and the directions are generally parallel. Finally, international comparisons are especially challenging because each country adheres to different accounting standards. Again, the general conclusions are unaffected and I’ve tried to keep things reconciled where possible—it’s not so much apples-to-oranges as tangerines-to-clementines in most cases.

In cases where quotes have been modified for readability, changes have been made only to nonsubstantive punctuation and capitalization (e.g., “Government is in Washington” appears as “government is in Washington” instead of “[g]overnment is in Washington”); otherwise, changes are noted. All emphases in quotations are mine unless otherwise noted

APPENDICES

APPENDIX A

Boomer Sociopathy—Ticking the Boxes

The evidence presented in the book will either persuade or not persuade readers that the Boomers behaved in antisocial (i.e., sociopathic) ways. Readers can intuit what antisocial personality disorders look like, and we could leave it at that. However, clinical guides are useful for framing the analysis.

The Diagnostic and Statistical Manual of Mental Disorders, Fifth Edition (“DSM-V”) is the psychiatric profession’s standard reference work for identifying disorders.1 The DSM-V contains two major diagnostic models—its standard model and its “emerging model.”2 These modes heavily overlap and are generally consistent. This book contends that under either model, the Boomers meet the clinical standards for “sociopathy”—i.e., “antisocial personality disorder.” The key difference between the two models is that the original model invokes a requirement of “conduct disorder” before age fifteen, and time has made that data hard to get, although the sustained attention to “juvenile delinquency” during the 1950s and 1960s (when the Boomers were under fifteen) is highly suggestive. In any event, the second model dispenses with this restriction.

Generally, each sociopathic individual must meet certain minimum criteria and this book presents population-wide data, with the exception of certain political figures whose personalities are well reported. In some cases, diagnostic criteria autocorrelate. Boomers who did drugs while on combat duty flouted the law, acted improvidently, displayed certain empathetic deficits, etc.: you can basically construct the checklist for one discrete individual. In other cases, conduct may or may not have overlapped, and some may wish to argue that, perhaps, all the Boomers who displayed improvidence (as manifested in the savings rate) did not manifest, say, lack of empathy. But that proposition of random bad behaviors not leading to a composite antisocial whole is very hard to believe, given the vast populations involved and the necessary implications of some actions—e.g., in the case of savings, that the lack of savings and improvidently low tax rates necessarily mean that other generations will have to bear the consequences of Boomer consumption (demonstrating lack of empathy). We can go on like this all the way through.

The DSM-V is, like all works of its kind, filled with various qualifiers, restrictions on use, and so on. It’s designed to diagnose individuals, not broad demographic groups, but as this book is not medicating anyone or consigning them to an asylum, the DSM-V provides an important guide to thinking about Boomer behaviors.

* For this book, I treat the Boomers as generally white and always native-born, for reasons that will become clear in Chapter 1, and also because the lives of certain minorities, especially of blacks, were significantly different from those of whites, who formed the vast majority of the Boom. From time to time, minorities do make an appearance in the book, because how the Boomers treated their minority cogenerationalists often fell well below stated ideals, but to do justice to the minority experience requires an entirely separate book.

NOTES


Foreword

  1. Robins, Lee N., and Darrel A. Regier. Psychiatric Disorders in America. The Free Press, 1991, ch. 11. The ECA study was based on surveys and work conducted by UCLA and Yale, Johns Hopkins, Washington, and Duke universities, with a large population in five mainly urban sites, and coordinated with the National Institutes of Mental Health in the first half of the 1980s; the findings were generalized to national populations using 1980s Census data. It used definitions from the third version of the DSM, which had the same general concept of antisocial personality disorder as the fifth and current version, though with slightly different criteria. Not only did ECA find that the prevalence of antisocial personality disorder was higher in Boomer-age cohorts, it also speculated that lifetime prevalence might have been understated relative to older groups, as Boomers had not had as much time to accumulate symptoms.
    Introduction
  2. Reagan, Ronald. “Ronald Reagan’s Announcement for Presidential Candidacy.” National Archives, 13 Nov. 1979, www.reaganlibrary.archives.gov/archives/reference/11.13.79.html. Reagan attributed this sentiment to “someone,” probably a speechwriter, but wholeheartedly endorsed it.
  3. Taylor, Paul, et al. “Once Again, the Future Ain’t What It Used to Be.” Pew Research Center, 2 May 2006, www.pewresearch.org/files/old-assets/social/pdf/BetterOff.pdf (citing data from 2002, 2006); Stokes, Bruce. “Global Publics: Economic Conditions Are Bad: But Positive Sentiment Rebounding in Europe, Japan, U.S.” Pew Research Center, 23 July 2015, www.pewglobal.org/files/2015/07/Pew-Research-Center-Economy-Report-FINAL-July-23-20151.pdf (citing data from 2015).
  4. United States Constitution. Preamble.
  5. Buettner, Russ, and Charles V. Bagli. “How Donald Trump Bankrupted His Atlantic City Casinos, but Still Earned Billions.” New York Times, 11 June 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/06/12/nyregion/donald-trump-atlantic-city.html?_r=0; Carroll, Lauren, and Clayton Youngman. “Fact-Checking Claims About Donald Trump’s Four Bankruptcies.” Politifact, 21 Sept. 2015, www.politifact.com/truth-o-meter/statements/2015/sep/21/carly-fiorina/trumps-four-bankruptcies/; Isidore, Chris. “Everything You Want to Know about Donald Trump’s Bankruptcies.” CNN, 31 Aug. 2015, money.cnn.com/2015/08/31/news/companies/donald-trump-bankruptcy/; Harwell, Drew, and Jacob Bogage. “What Trump Didn’t Say About His Four Big Business Bankruptcies.” Washington Post, 7 Aug. 2015, www.washingtonpost.com/business/economy/what-trump-didnt-say-about-his-four-big-business-bankruptcies/2015/08/07/bc054e64-3d12-11e5-9c2d-ed991d848c48_story.html. Trump admitted his casinos filed for bankruptcy in several places, including the Republican primary debates and in an interview with ABC.
  6. White House, Council of Economic Advisers. “The 2015 Economic Report of the President.” Economic Report of the President, Feb. 2015, ch. 1, p. 39, www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/docs/cea_2015_erp_complete.pdf. The Report is technically presented by the president to Congress, but it’s fairly clear that the CEA does most of the heavy lifting.
  7. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. “Real Median Family Income in the United States” (MEFAINUSA672N), www.research.stlouisfed.org (using data from the US Census). The St. Louis Fed both produces its own data and aggregates data from other sources, primarily government sources. Because the St. Louis Fed’s online database is used frequently and is a convenient source for readers, I will frequently refer to this source (hereinafter “FRED”), noting the applicable series identifier and, if FRED’s data are based on sources other than the Federal Reserve Bank, the institution providing that data in a series’s first mention. In the case of family income, the statistics presented are for 2015, in CPI-U-RS inflation-but-not-seasonally-adjusted terms (essentially, 2015 dollars). It’s important to note that recent economic data are constantly revised, and exhibit some minor fluctuations as final data are collected. Usually, after a few quarters, the economists achieve consensus at a final number. These fluctuations may account for certain minor differences between figures quoted in this book, in the press, and even by a given government agency within a few-week period, but do not change any general conclusions or raise any questions about the long-term data herein or the reliability of government data generally (though the government’s conclusions are often suspect, the more political and less technical the data are). See “A Note on the Numbers and Conventions” for further discussion.
  8. Ibid.; US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (hereinafter “BEA”), Consumer Price Index; author’s calculations. For this chapter, I’ve used Census’s “family incomes” because they have a longer and more consistent history than “median household incomes.” The latter is a more common metric now, but it has a more complicated history than family income. Both statistics drive toward the same conclusion: Analyzing any reasonable metric reveals a significant gap between projected and actual income, whether that metric is family income, household income or GDP per capita, and so on. (The projected/actual gaps for GPD per capita are smaller, because they would be an average, and blend in the concentration of wealth at the top—though incomes would still be higher even under that analysis). Because counterfactuals over such long periods draw in so many different variables, this endnote is a long one. First, the composition of American families has changed over time but that in itself is partly an economic choice and the general conclusion remains the same even adjusting for changes to family composition. Second, the “mid” scenario encompasses 1981–82, years of recession, while the “actual” series includes 2015, well into the recovery, so if anything, the case is being somewhat understated. Third, it’s important to acknowledge that the ways Americans earn income have changed over the years (and how the Census has changed its calculations of income, most recently in the 2013–2014 period which resulted in a 2 to 3 percent jump due to methodology alone). These factors can push the numbers around, but again, they don’t change the general direction or rough magnitude of the gap. For example, many Americans work longer hours and more people in American multi-person families work now than they did in the 1950s (so if anything, one could argue that incomes should be even higher). At the same time, people start working later in life and for several decades have been compensated partly in non-cash income which is nevertheless quite valuable and important (like certain health and retirement benefits)—factoring these items in would narrow the gap between actual and potential but not come close to erasing it. (This is especially the case considering the formerly greater availability of defined benefit contributions before the 1980s. The picture darkens when you consider that older people who received employer contributions to retirement plans/Social Security have a much better chance of collecting from those plans at promised value than younger people today will.) All in all, principled cases could be made that projected incomes could be higher or lower than I estimated, but even heavy tweaking still leaves a gap and that gap really grows as the Boomers accumulate power. You’d expect major departures by the late 1980s or early 1990s (a hysteresis) and this is essentially what happens. It’s worth noting that the Economic Report of the President completed a similar counterfactual in its 2015 Report and found that household incomes would be 98 percent higher had certain positive trends continued, which is a stronger claim than I advance here. See supra en 5 at pp. 29–34.
  9. “64–65 NY World’s Fair FUTURAMA Ride Video,” www.youtube.com/watch?v=2-5aK0H05jk#action=share.
  10. The estimated population at the time I turned in the final draft of this book was 324 million; it was about 321 when I first started working on the book. US Department of Commerce, US Census Bureau (hereinafter “US Census”). Population Estimates, Intercensal Estimates (various periods).
  11. Diagnostic and Statistical Manual of Mental Disorders: DSM-5. Washington, DC: 2013 (hereinafter “DSM-V”), 764 (alternative model); cf. ibid. at 659 (default model). A discussion of the specific application of the DSM-V’s various criteria and caveats about their application appear in Appendix A to this book.
  12. Office of the Independent Counsel. The Starr Report. Submitted by Kenneth W. Starr, endnote 1091, 9 Sept. 1998, www.washingtonpost.com/wp-srv/politics/special/clinton/icreport/srprintable.htm.
    Chapter 1: The View from 1946
  13. Quoted in Hayden, Deborah. Pox: Genius, Madness and the Mysteries of Syphilis. Basic Books, 2003, p. 133.
  14. Ibid., pp. 137–138.
  15. US Census, Current Population Surveys (various years and intercesal estimates); Centers for Disease Control and Prevention’s (“CDC”) Population Estimates (same); author’s calculations.
  16. Ibid.; US Census, “Current Estimates Data” Population Estimates, 2015, www.census.gov/popest/data/index.html.; CDC. “Live Births, Birth Rates, and Fertility Rates, by Race: 1909–2003.” Vital Statistics of the United States, Table 1–1, www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/statab/natfinal2003.annvol1_01.pdf; US Census. “Death Rates by Age, Sex, and Race: 1950 to 2008.” Statistical Abstract of the United States, Tables 110, 2012 (various years), available for 2011 at census.gov/library/publications/2011/compendia/statab/131ed/tables/12s0110.pdf; author’s calculations.
  17. “October 28, 1980 Debate Transcript: the Carter-Reagan Presidential Debate.” Commission on Presidential Debates, 28 Oct. 1980, www.debates.org/index.php?page=october-28-1980-debate-transcript.
  18. Department of Veterans Affairs, Office of Public Affairs. “America’s Wars.” www.va.gov/opa/publications/factsheets/fs_americas_wars.pdf; US Public Health Services, National Office of Vital Statistics. “Vital Statistics of the United States 1945, part I.” Prepared under the supervision of Halbert L. Dunn, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/vsus/vsus_1945_1.pdf.
  19. Haskew, Michael E., ed., The World War II Desk Reference, Castle Books, 2008 at 433–35; author’s calculations. “War deaths” includes civilian and combat deaths. Figures for American civilian casualities are not available, but are usually assumed to range from negligible to up to 120,000, which is a tiny fraction of the 16 million estimated civilian deaths in the Soviet Union, the 6 million in Poland, and the 13 million in China. There is considerable debate about the exact numbers each nation lost, but the general conclusion is that German, Chinese, and Soviet losses were immense—tens of millions.
  20. Davidson, Justin. “The Kitchen Debate’s Actual Kitchen.” New York, 8 May 2011, nymag.com/realestate/features/commack-moscow-2011-5/.
  21. Ibid.; US Census, Current Population Reports, Current Income (1961) at table B (for 1959 incomes).
  22. Zillow.com; FRED, MEFAINUSA672N. Long Island is a different place now and 358 Towline Road has had some upgrades over the years, which explains some of the relative price increase. Nevertheless, housing consumes a larger share of income for many Americans than it once did, with significant geographic variability; it is, to be reductive, costlier.
  23. National Bureau of Economic Research. Clotfelter, Charles T. “Patterns of Enrollment and Completion.” Jan. 1991, pp. 30–31.
  24. FRED, UNRATE (BEA). A full discussion of unemployment trends is in Chapter 15 of this book.
  25. “American Machine & Foundry Company.” Harvard Business School, Lehman Brothers Collection—Contemporary Business Archives, www.library.hbs.edu/hc/lehman/company.html?company=american_machine_foundry_company.
  26. Public Law 89-10 (1965), Title II, §201 et seq. and subsequent reauthorizations at 20 USC §§6301 et seq.
  27. Brown v. Board of Education, 347 US 483 (1954).
  28. Social Security Administration. Life Expectancy for Social Security; CDC. Life tables 1900–2100.
  29. Tax Foundation. “Federal Individual Income Tax Rates History: Nominal Dollars: Income Years 1913–2013.” taxfoundation.org/sites/taxfoundation.org/files/docs/fed_individual_rate_history_nominal.pdf.
  30. Ibid. (maximum marginal taxes fell through the early 1960s, reaching 70 percent in 1965).
  31. FRED, GFDEGQ188S, FYFSGDA188S (US Office of Management and Budget, hereinafter “OMB”). Full discussion of debt and deficits appears in Chapter 9, as do additional and primary sources.
    Chapter 2: Bringing Up Boomer
  32. Locke, John. Some Thoughts Concerning Education, part I, § 1, open-source edition, undated (originally published 1693), https://the federalistpapers.integratedmarket.netdna-cdn.com.wp-content/uploads/2012/12/John-Locke-Thoughts-Concerning-Education.pdf.
  33. Ibid., Dedication.
  34. DSM-V, p. 661.
  35. Brody, Jane E. “Final Advice from Dr. Spock: Eat Only All Your Vegetables.” New York Times, 20 June 1998, www.nytimes.com/1998/06/20/us/final-advice-from-dr-spock-eat-only-all-your-vegetables.html.
  36. Maier, Thomas. Dr. Spock: An American Life. Basic Books, 2nd ed., 2003, pp. 199, 202.
  37. Ibid., p.130 (quoting Spock, Benjamin. The Common Sense Book of Baby and Child Care. 1st ed., Duell, Sloan and Pearce, 14 July 1946). Multiple editions of the Common Sense Book have been issued, and Maier has been cross-checked against the Common Sense Book.
  38. Quoted in Maier, pp. 138–139.
  39. Quoted in Maier, p. 321; see also Pace, Eric. “Benjamin Spock, World’s Pediatrician, Dies at 94.” New York Times, 17 Mar. 1998 (quoting Peale slightly differently, but to the same effect).
  40. US Department of Health and Human Services, US Public Health Service, Office of the Surgeon General. “The Surgeon General’s Call to Action to Support Breastfeeding.” 2011, pp. 1–5; Horta, Bernardo L., and Cesar G. Victoria. “Long-Term Effects of Breastfeeding: A Systematic Review.” World Health Organization, 2013, (a metastudy, noting a certain heterogeneity of data but many statistically significant outcomes, even adjusting for important variables like socioeconomic status and maternal IQ).
  41. “Childhood Lead Poisoning.” World Health Organization, 2010, p. 20 et seq.; Godwin, Hilary A. “Lead Exposure and Poisoning in Children.” UCLA Institute of the Environment and Sustainability. Southern California Environmental Report Card, 2009, www.environment.ucla.edu/reportcard/index.html; see also Reyes, Jessica Wolpaw. “Environmental Policy as Social Policy? The Impact of Childhood Lead Exposure on Crime.” National Bureau of Economic Research, May 2007, www.nber.org/papers/w13097 (for the effects of lead, but coming to different conclusions about generational criminality).
  42. US Department of Commerce, National Telecommunications and Information Administration. “Household Broadband Adoption Climbs to 72.4 Percent.” 6 June 2013, www.ntia.doc.gov/blog/2013/household-broadband-adoption-climbs-724-percent.
  43. US Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. “American Time Use Survey Summary.” 24 June 2016, tables 1 and 11, www.bls.gov/news.release/atus.nr0.htm. “Teenagers” are defined as fifteen-to-nineteen-year-olds by BLS.
  44. Maier, p. 401.
  45. Powers, John. “Documentary Revisits the ‘Dazzling’ Polemics of the Buckley-Vidal Debates.” NPR, 18 Aug. 2015, www.npr.org/2015/08/18/432721150/documentary-revisits-the-dazzling-polemics-of-the-buckley-vidal-debates; Holt, Jim. “Will Intellectual Combat Ever Top William Buckley vs. Gore Vidal? A New Documentary Suggests Not.” New York, 26 July 2015, nymag.com/daily/intelligencer/2015/07/best-of-enemies-buckley-vidal.html. Clips of the debates are available on YouTube, such as this one, with the relevant portion starting around 10:30, https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ZY_nq4tfi24.
  46. 13 FCC 1246 (1949) and codified in multiple releases afterward.
  47. 48 FCC 2d 1 (FCC 1974).
  48. Davis, Horance G. “TV: Just an Appliance… Toaster with Pictures.” Hendersonville Times-News (a NYT regional newspaper), 29 Aug. 1987, p. 4; Syracuse Peach Council, 2 FCC Rcd 5043 (1987).
  49. “What Americans Know: 1989–2007: Public Knowledge of Current Affairs Little Changed by News and Information Revolutions.” Pew Research Center for the People & the Press, 15 Apr. 2007, p. 13, www.people-press.org/files/legacy-pdf/319.pdf.
  50. The Impact of Television: A Natural Experiment in Three Communities. Edited by Tannis MacBeth Williams, Academic Press, 1986, pp. 2–4, and 14, and tables 1.3–.4.
  51. Ibid., pp. 51–52, 61, see also 66 and compare pp.105–106, 120–121.
  52. Ibid., p. 67.
  53. Ibid., pp. 334, 412.
  54. Ibid., ch. 9.
  55. Winn, Marie. The Plug In Drug. Penguin Books, 3rd ed., 2002, p.109 (quoting NIMH, and referring to studies cited therein); see also, Hancox, Robert, et al. “Association of Television Viewing during Childhood with Poor Educational Achievement.” Journal of the American Medical Association, vol. 159, July 2005, p. 615 et seq. (noting that the “associations between child and adolescent television viewing and education outcomes [which were negative] persisted after adjusting for IQ, socioeconomic status, and childhood behavioral problems,” in a 1972 NZ cohort); Ridley-Johnson, Robyn, et al., “The Relation of Children’s Television Viewing to School Achievement and I.Q.” Journal of Educational Research, vol. 76, no. 5, May–June 1983, p. 294. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/27539990; Borzekowski, Dina L.G., et al., “The Remote, the Mouse, and the No. 2 Pencil: The Household Media Environment and Academic Achievement Among Third Grade Students.” Archives of Pediatric Adolescent Medicine, vol. 159, no. 7, 1 July 2005, pp. 607–613 (significantly negative effects for children with a TV in the bedroom, controlling for other variables); but compare Gentzkow, Matthew, and Jesse M. Shapiro. “Preschool Television Viewing and Adolescent Test Scores: Historical Evidence from the Coleman Study.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 123, no. 1, Feb. 2008. Oxford Journals, qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/123/1/279.short (finding essentially no effects). See also Wright, John C., et al. “The Relations of Early Television Viewing to School Readiness and Vocabulary of Children from Low-Income Families: The Early Window Project,” Child Development, vol. 72, no. 5, Sept.–Oct. 2001, pp. 1347–1366 (finding educational content may have small positive effects, but general content has negative effects in studied group).
  56. Winn, p. 109.
  57. Associated Press. “Coast Survey of Students Links Rise in TV Use to Poorer Grades.” New York Times, 9 Nov. 1980.
  58. Morin, Rich, and Paul Taylor. “Luxury or Necessity? The Public Makes A U-Turn.” Pew Research Center, Social & Demographic Trends, 23 Apr. 2009, p. 9, www.pewsocialtrends.org/files/2010/10/luxury-or-necessity-2009.pdf.
  59. Marsiglia, Cheryl S., et al. “Impact of Parenting Styles and Locus of Control on Emerging Adults’ Psychosocial Success.” Journal of Education and Human Development, vol. 1, no. 1, 2007. “Authoritative” parenting, which is somewhere between permissive and authoritarian, produces the best outcomes.
    Chapter 3: Vietnam and the Emerging Boomer Identity
  60. Johnson, Samuel. “The Idler.” The Works of Samuel Johnson, Vol. 7, Essay No. 30, at 120. A. Strahan, 1801.
  61. Rucker, Philip. “Trump Slams McCain for Being ‘Captured’ in Vietnam; Other Republicans Quickly Condemn Him.” Washington Post, 18 Jul. 2015, www.washingtonpost.com/news/post-politics/wp/2015/07/18/trump-slams-mccain-for-being-captured-in-vietnam/; Felsenthal, Carol. “Bernie Sanders Found Socialism at the University of Chicago.” Chicago Magazine, 4 Feb. 2015. There are some lingering questions about whether Sanders could have, in good conscience, applied for CO status, since it required at the time a religious objection to all wars, which it’s not clear he had. But Hillary Clinton’s primary win mooted the matter.
  62. US Census Bureau. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2014. Tables 3, 7; author’s calculations.
  63. Loewe, James W. Lies My Teacher Told Me: Everything Your American History Textbook Got Wrong. 2nd ed., New Press, 2007, pp. 244–245 and 255–256.
  64. Daggett, Stephen. “Costs of Major U.S. Wars.” Library of Congress, Congressional Research Service, 29 Jun 2010, p. 2 et seq. Figures cited are for the wars themselves; the defense budget was higher in the 1940s–1960s overall than it would be during the later conflicts in the Middle East. It is reasonable to debate which basis—all defense, or just combat operations—is the right metric, though it’s important to remember that the secular trend in mid-century America was for large defense budgets overall as a fraction of national income.
  65. Free, Lloyd A., and Hadley Cantril. The Political Beliefs of Americans: A Study of Public Opinion. Rutgers University Press, 1967, pp. 59–60 (citing May 1964 Gallup polling; about a quarter of Americans were unaware “about the fighting in Vietnam”).
  66. DSM-V, p. 659.
  67. Pub. Law 51-144 §1.c-d (1951). The twists, turns, and complexities of the draft are mind-numbing now, but were studied intently during the war. We can gloss over many of the system’s quirks without losing the general point, although the quirks themselves provide interesting test beds whose implications are discussed later.
  68. US Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1966. Table 366; Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1976. Table 541; author’s calculations.
  69. 81 Stat. 102 §6.a.1,.h.1 (1967); see also Selective Service System. Annual Report of the Director of Selective Service, 1967, p.14 et seq.
  70. Reports of the Director of the Selective Service (various years); see also note 9.
  71. Lunch, William L., and Peter Sperlich. “American Public Opinion and the War in Vietnam.” Western Political Quarterly, vol. 32, no. 1, Mar. 1979, p. 24. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/447561.
  72. Ibid., pp. 32–33.
  73. Appleton, Sheldon. “The Public, the Polls, and the War.” Vietnam Perspectives, vol. 1, no. 4, May 1966, pp. 3–13.
  74. Ibid., pp. 24, 33; see also Erksine, Hazel. “The Polls, Pacifism and the Generation Gap.” Public Opinion Quarterly, vol. 36, no. 4, 1972–73, pp. 616–627; Erksine, Hazel. “The Polls: Is War a Mistake.” Public Opinion Quarterly, vol. 34, no. 1, 1970, pp. 134–159.
  75. Carroll, Joseph. “The Iraq–Vietnam Comparison.” Gallup Inc., 15 June 2004, www.gallup.com/poll/11998/iraqvietnam-comparison.aspx.
  76. Erskine, “The Polls: Is War a Mistake,” pp. 134–135.
  77. “Every Person of the Year Cover Ever.” Time, time.com/3614128/person-of-the-year-covers/.
  78. Baskir, Lawrence M., and William A. Strauss; see also this chapter’s note 9, Chance and Circumstance: The Draft, the War and the Vietnam Generation. Alfred A. Knopf., 1st ed., 1978, pp. 4–6, Fig 1.
  79. Foley, Michael S. Confronting the War Machine: Draft Resistance During the Vietnam War. University of North Carolina Press, 2003, p. 37.
  80. Selective Service System. Annual Report of the Director of Selective Service, 1967, p. 16.
  81. Baskir, Strauss, Fig. 1. See also this chapter’s note 9.
  82. Foley, pp. 39–40.
  83. Kuziemko, Ilyana. “‘Dodging Up’ to College or ‘Dodging Down’ to Jail: Behavioral Responses to the Vietnam Draft by Race and Class.” Princeton University and National Board of Economic Research, 2010; and Kuziemko, Ilyana. “Did the Vietnam Draft Increase Human Capital Dispersion? Draft-Avoidance Behavior by Race and Class.” Princeton University and National Board of Economic Research, Jan. 2010.
  84. Miller, Glenn T. Piety and Profession: American Protestant Theological Education, 1870–1970. Wm. B. Eerdmans, 2007, p. 699, and footnotes 55, 728. John C. Stocker conducted similar research and reached concurrent conclusions in work for the Lilly Foundation.
  85. Kuziemko, “‘Dodging Up’ to College or ‘Dodging Down’ to Jail”; Card, David, and Thomas Lemieux. “Going to College to Avoid the Draft: The Unintended Legacy of the Vietnam War.” American Economic Review, vol. 91, no. 2, May 2001, pp. 97–102. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/2677740; Associated Press. “College Enrollment Linked to Vietnam War.” New York Times, 2 Sept. 1984, www.nytimes.com/1984/09/02/us/college-enrollment-linked-to-vietnam-war.html (citing research by the Census Bureau); Opportunity, no. 113, Nov. 2011, pp. 2–3 (noting anomalous spike in male enrollment not paralleled in women during draft period).
  86. Graham, Fred P. “Spock and Coffin Indicted for Activity against Draft.” The New York Times, 6 Jan. 1968, www.nytimes.com/books/98/05/17/specials/spock-indicted.html.
  87. Maraniss, David. First in His Class: The Biography of Bill Clinton, Touchstone, 1996, pp. 188–194; see also Ifill, Gwen. “The 1992 Campaign: New Hampshire: Clinton Thanked Colonel in ’69 for ‘Saving Me from the Draft.’” New York Times, 13 Feb. 1992 (reprinting Clinton’s rather confusing letter to his ROTC director); Ifill, Gwen. “The 1992 Campaign: Democrats; Vietnam War Draft Status Becomes Issue for Clinton.” New York Times, 7 Feb. 1992; Brokaw, Tom, et al. “Bill Clinton Tries to Defend Himself on Draft Issue.” NBC Nightly News, 15 Sept. 1992, archives.nbclearn.com/portal/site/k-12/flatview?cuecard=33559.
  88. Seelye, Katharine Q. “The 2004 Campaign: Military Service; Cheney’s Five Draft Deferments during the Vietnam Era Emerge as a Campaign Issue.” New York Times, 1 May 2004, nytimes.com/2004/05/01/us/2004-campaign-military-service-cheney-s-five-draft-deferments-during-vietnam-era.html.
  89. Foley, p. 51.
  90. Appy, Christian G. Working-Class War: American Combat Soldiers & Vietnam. University of North Carolina Press, 1993, p. 27; see also Baskir, Strauss, pp. 6–9 and ch. 2 generally.
  91. Timberg, Robert. John McCain: An American Odyssey. 1st paperback ed., Free Press, 2007, p. 122.
  92. Foley, p.12.
  93. Baskir and Strauss, pp. 40–41 (172,000 CO classifications); and US Census Bureau. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1977, table 598 (179,000 CO classifications between 1965 and 1975); see also Selective Service System. Semi-Annual Report of Director of Selective Service, 1973, Appendix 12 (noting about 300,000 classifications); Fox, Richard P. “Conscientious Objection to War: The Background and a Current Appraisal.” Cleveland State Law Review, 1982, p. 90; Levi, Margaret. Consent, Dissent, and Patriotism. Cambridge University Press, 1997, pp. 164–173. Because of the way CO objections were processed, compilers occasionally double-counted; the consensus is that about 175,000 CO classifications were made and even the largest figures noted were just a tiny fraction of other deferment types.
  94. Kuziemko,“‘Dodging Up’ to College or ‘Dodging Down’ to Jail”; Kuziemko, “Did the Vietnam Draft Increase Human Capital Dispersion?” p. 2 and secs. 5–6.
  95. Ibid.
  96. Kuziemko,“‘Dodging Up’ to College or ‘Dodging Down’ to Jail,” p. 22.
  97. Baskir and Strauss, pp. 126–129.
  98. Anderson, Terry H. The Sixties, Pearson, 2012, pp. 79–80; Baskir and Strauss, pp. 8–9.
  99. DSM-V, pp. 660–61.
  100. Heinl, Robert D. “The Collapse of the Armed Forces.” Armed Forces Journal. North American Newspaper Alliance, 7 June 1971, reprinted in Gettleman, Marvin, et al. Vietnam and America: A Documented History. Grove Press. 1995, pp. 326–336.
  101. Ibid., p. 329.
  102. Brush, Peter. “The Hard Truth about Fragging.” Vietnam Magazine, Oct. 2010, pp. 40–43.
  103. Anderson, p. 167.
  104. Baskir and Strauss, pp. 134–136.
  105. Bell, Bruce D. “Characteristics of Army Deserters in the DoD Special Discharge Review Program.” Research Report 1229. US Army Research Institute for the Behavioral and Social Sciences, Oct. 1979, p. 2 and n. 4.
  106. Heinl, in Gettleman, p. 334.
  107. Karnow, Stanley. Vietnam: A History. 2nd ed., Penguin Books Group, 1997, p. 20.
  108. Plato. Crito (generally).
  109. Stern, Lewis M. “Response to Vietnamese Refugees: Surveys of Public Opinion.” Social Work: A Journal of the National Association of Social Workers, vol. 26, no. 4, 1981, pp. 306 et seq.
  110. Elliott, Debbie. “A Lesson in History: Resettling Refugees of Vietnam.” All Things Considered, 14 Jan. 2007; State Department Archives. “Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976, vol. X, Vietnam, January 1973–July 1975.” Document 263, 1976, history.state.gov/historicaldocuments/frus1969-76v10/d263; see also for a partisan opinion, Pham, Quang X. “Ford’s Finest Legacy.” Washington Post, 30 Dec. 2006, www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/12/29/AR2006122901070.html. Chapman, Bruce. “As Governor, Jerry Brown Was Vociferous Foe of Vietnamese Immigration.” Discovery News, 2 Oct. 2010.
  111. Hunter, Marjorie. “Ford Offers Amnesty Program Requiring 2 Years Public Work; Defends His Pardon of Nixon.” New York Times, 17 Sept. 1974, p. 1. Estimates varied as to numbers eligible for clemency; the government cited figures that were probably too low and were in any event rendered moot by Carter’s subsequent pardon. Moreover, under Ford’s clemency, the two-year term could be reduced for “mitigating” circumstances like family hardship, so it’s not clear that much penance really would have been required.
    Chapter 4: Empire of Self
  112. DSM-V, p. 662.
  113. Ibid., pp. 660–61.
  114. Swatz, James A. Substance Abuse in America: A Documentary and Reference Guide. Greenwood, 2012, p. 158; West of Center: Art and the Counter Culture Experiment in America, 1965–1977. Edited by Elissa Auther and Adam Lerner. University of Minnesota Press, 2 Nov. 2011, p. 57.
  115. “Protest: The Banners of Dissent.” Time. 27 Oct. 1967, content.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,841090,00.html.
  116. Gitlin, Todd. The Sixties: Years of Hope, Days of Rage. Revised ed., Bantam, 1 July 1993, p. 214.
  117. Cottrell, Robert C. Sex, Drugs and Rock ’n’ Roll: The Rise of America’s 1960s Counterculture. Rowman & Littlefield, 19 Mar. 2015, p. 88.
  118. The New York Times: The Times of the Sixties: The Culture, Politics and Personalities That Shaped the Decades. Edited by John Rockwell. Black Dog & Leventhal, 2014, p. 152.
  119. “Gallup Finds Rise in Marijuana Use,” New York Times, 6. Feb. 1972, p. 36 (polling college students and finding under 5 percent had tried marijuana in 1967, rising to 42 percent by 1970 and then a majority by the end of 1971; of that majority, four out of five had used it in the past year and three out of five in the past month). See also Golub, Andrew, Bruce D. Johnson, “The Rise of Marijuana as the Drug of Choice Among Youthful Adult Arrestees,” June 2001, US Department of Justice, at 6 (citing data for general population derived from the National Household Survey on Drug Abuse et al). See also Robison, Jennifer. “Decades of Drug Use: Data from the ’60s and ’70s.” Gallup, 2 July 2002, http://www.gallup.com/poll/6331/decades-drug-use-data-from-60s-70s.aspx (marijuana use among all adults under 5 percent in the late 1960s).
  120. See notes 8 and 10.
  121. Harrison, Lana D., et al. “Cannabis Use in the United States: Implications for Policy.” University of Delaware, Center for Drug and Alcohol Studies, 12 Jun. 1995, pp. 181–183. CEDRO, www.cedro-uva.org/lib/harrison.cannabis.pdf; National Commission on Marijuana and Drug Abuse. “Marihuana: A Signal of Misunderstanding.” Commissioned by President Richard M. Nixon, Mar. 1972; see also Johnston, Lloyd D., et al. “Monitoring the Future: National Survey Results on Drug Use 1975–2014,” vol. 2, 2014, p. 27, tables 9.15 et seq. (sponsored by NIDA and NIH).
  122. Johnston, “Monitoring the Future,” tables 9.10, 9.12, 9.15.
  123. National Institute on Drug Abuse. “DrugFacts, Nationwide Trends.” (rev. 2015, most recent data from 2013 surveys), p. 2, www.drugabuse.gov/sites/default/files/drugfacts_nationtrends_6_15.pdf.
  124. Twenge, Jean M., et al. “Changes in American Adults’ Sexual Behavior and Attitudes 1972–2012.” Archives of Sexual Behavior, 2014–2015, psy2.fau.edu/~shermanr/Twenge%20Sherman%20&%20Wells%20In%20Press.pdf at 2273 in journal form.
  125. Ibid., Finer, Lawrence B., and Jesse M Philbin. “Trends in Ages at Key Reproductive Transitions in the United States, 1951–2010.” Women’s Health Issues. May–June 2014, pp. 5–6 (electronic version).
  126. Ibid.; see also Twenge, Jean M., et al. “Changes in American Adults’ Sexual Behavior and Attitudes 1972–2012.” The Millennials do appear to have very promiscuous subcohorts.
  127. Ibid. at 2280. The number of partners peaked in the cohort born during the 1960s generally, and so includes some GenXers. The data cited are not sufficiently granular to make a precise break at 1964.
  128. Ibid.
  129. Twenge, “Changes in American Adults’ Sexual Behavior and Attitudes 1972–2012,” at 2279.
  130. DSM-V at 660.
  131. Griswold v. Connecticut, 381 US 479 (1965); Eisenstadt v. Baird, 405 US 438 (1972).
  132. Kost, Kathryn, and Stanley Henshaw. “U.S. Teenage Pregnancies, Births and Abortions 2010: National and State Trends by Age, Race and Ethnicity.” Guttmacher Institute, May 2014, table 2.1.
  133. Cowan, Sarah K. “Cohort Abortion Measures for the United States.” Population and Development Review, vol. 39, no. 2, June 2013, p. 9, fig. 6, table 1. HHS Public Access.
  134. Ibid., p 10.
  135. Ibid., table 2.1.
  136. CDC. “2014 Sexually Transmitted Disease Surveillance 2014.” 2015, tables 10, 21, 35. The CDC data are the most reliable data available, although methodology and collection are imperfect due to state inconsistencies in collection. Given the size of n, however, CDC’s conclusions should be considered generally reliable.
  137. DSM-V, pp. 660–61, 764.
  138. Foreman, Amanda. “The Heartbreaking History of Divorce.” Smithsonian Magazine, Feb. 2014.
  139. Wilcox, W. Bradford. “The Evolution of Divorce.” National Affairs, 2009, p. 81.
  140. US Census. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1998, table no. 123 and subsequent years at comparable tables; see also US Census Bureau. “Number, Timing, and Duration of Marriages and Divorces: 2009.” Current Population Report: Household Economic Studies, May 2011, pp. 7–10; Thomas, Susan Gregory. “The Divorce Generation.” Wall Street Journal, 9 July 2011. Saturday Essay. Because divorce is politicized, not all states compile good data, federal funding for collection of data was restricted in the 1990s, and divorce data are notoriously hard to pin down, but the general trend in divorce can be discerned readily enough.
  141. Kennedy, Sheela, and Steven Ruggles. “Breaking Up Is Hard to Count: The Rise of Divorce in the United States, 1980–2010.” Demography, 8 Jan. 2014, p. 595, and cites associated with figures presented in this chapter for the rise in marital instability after 1970. Boomers are now late middle-aged or senior, but their pattern of high marital instability continues. Subsequent generations do marry less frequently, and later, and their lower incidence of divorce is affected by those trends, since those who are not married cannot, by definition, get divorced.
  142. Brown, Susan L., and I-Fen Lin. “The Gray Divorce Revolution: Rising Divorce Among Middle-Aged and Older Adults, 1990–2010.” Journals of Gerontology Series B, vol. 67, no. 6, 2012, pp. 731–741; see generally Thomas, Susan Gregory. “The Gray Divorcés.” Wall Street Journal, 3 Mar. 2012. Saturday Essay.
  143. Brown, and Lin. “The Gray Divorce Revolution”; see generally Thomas, “The Gray Divorcés,” and see also cites associated with figures presented herein.
  144. Thomas (citing Strauss, William, and Neil Howe. Generations: The History of America’s Future, 1584 to 2069. Quill, 30. Sept. 1992). I have my own doubts about Generations generally, but other literature supports its pithy summary.
  145. Whitehead, Barbara Dafoe. The Divorce Culture: Rethinking our Commitments to Marriage and Family. Vintage, 3 Feb. 1998.
  146. “Number, Timing, and Duration of Marriages and Divorces: 2009.” US Census Bureau, 2009, table 4, www.census.gov/prod/2011pubs/p70-125.pdf; author’s calculations.
  147. For a good summary, see Arkowitz, Hal, and Scott O. Lilienfield. “Is Divorce Bad for Children? The Breakup May Be Painful, but Most Kids Adjust Well over Time.” Scientific American, 1 Mar. 2013; see also Amato, Paul R., and Jacob Cheadle, “The Long Reach of Divorce: Divorce and Child Well-Being Across Three Generations.” Journal of Marriage and Family, vol. 67, no. 1, Feb. 2005, pp. 192–193 et seq. and works cited therein.
  148. Brown, p. 731.
  149. DSM-V, p. 660.
  150. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. PSAVERT (BEA). The personal savings rate is the rate for individuals, nonprofit institutions, pensions, and assorted entities, but it’s the best proxy on a longitudinal basis for individual savings as a percent of disposable income. For a further discussion of savings, see Chapter 12.
  151. Ibid.
  152. CDC. “Prevalence of Obesity Among Adults,” and “Prevalence of Overweight, Obesity, and Extreme Obesity Among Adults: United States, Trends, 1960–1962 Through 2009–2010.” CDC, National Center for Health Statistics. “Health, United States, 2015: With Special Feature on Racial and Ethnic Health Disparities.” 2016, table 58, www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/hus/hus15.pdf#053.
  153. World Health Organization, Global Health Observatory Data Repository, apps.who.int/gho/data/node.main.A900A?lang=en (data for 2010 and 2014).
  154. CDC. “Prevalence of Overweight and Obesity among Children and Adolescents: United States, 1963–1965 through 2011–2012.” Sept. 2014.
  155. See notes 41–43; see also Leveille, Suzanne G. “Trends in Obesity and Arthritis Among Baby Boomers and Their Predecessors, 1971–2002.” American Journal of Public Health, vol. 95, no. 9, Sept. 2005, p. 1607 et seq.; compare Reuters. “Obesity Rates for Elderly, Middle Aged on the Rise.” Huffington Post, 25 Oct. 2012, www.huffingtonpost.com/2012/10/25/obesity-rates-elderly-middle-aged-rise_n_2017221.html.
  156. See note 44.
  157. Wang, Claire, et al. “Health and Economic Burden of the Projected Obesity Trends in the USA and the UK.” Lancet 378, no. 9793, 27 Aug. 2011, pp. 812–825. The excess health-care costs are estimated to be on the order of tens of billions, possibly offset if obese people simply die earlier.
  158. Wolfe, Tom. “Reports on America’s New Great Awakening: The ‘Me’ Decade.” New York, 23 Aug. 1976; see also Lasch, Christopher. The Culture of Narcissism, American Life in an Age of Diminishing Expectations. W. W. Norton, 1979; and Lasch’s essays from the 1970s.
  159. Hutchinson, Lydia. “The Rolling Stones’ ‘I Can’t Get No Satisfaction.’” Performing Songwriter. 26 July 2013, performingsongwriter.com/rolling-stones-satisfaction/.
  160. Twenge, Jean M., et al. “Changes in Pronoun Use in American Books and the Rise of Individualism, 1960–1980.” Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, vol. 43, no. 3, 2012, p. 408, and generally pp. 406–415.
  161. Ibid.
  162. Ibid.; see also Google gram.
  163. DSM-V, p. 660.
  164. Bradley, Stefan M. Harlem vs. Columbia University: Black Student Power in the Late 1960s. University of Illinois Press. 2009, pp. 74–85; see also Fraser, Ronald. 1968: A Student Generation in Revolt. Pantheon, 12 Apr. 1988, pp. 195–199; Martin, Douglas. “Henry S. Coleman, 79, Dies; Hostage at Columbia in ’68.” New York Times, 4 Feb. 2006. There have been self-serving assertions by students that Coleman had been ordered to stay in his office by the administration.
  165. Anderson, p. 108.
  166. Cf. Adler, Margot. “1968 Columbia Protests Still Stir Passion.” NPR. 23 Apr. 2008 (statement of Allen Silver).
  167. Twenge, Jean M., et al. “Changes in American Adults’ Sexual Behavior and Attitudes 1972–2012,” Archives of Sexual Behavior, vol. 44, no. 8, Nov. 2015, and various, esp. 9.
  168. “Distracted by Technology at Mealtimes—It’s Not Who You Think.” Nielsen, 11 Nov. 2015, nielsen.com/us/en/insights/news/2015/distracted-by-technology-at-mealtimes-its-not-who-you-may-think.html.
    Chapter 5: Science and Sentimentality
  169. Pearce, Matt. “U.S. Rep. Paul Broun: Evolution a Lie from ‘the Pit of Hell,’” Los Angeles Times, 7 Oct. 2012.
  170. Berlin, Isaiah. Against the Current. 2nd ed., Princeton University Press. 2013, p. 205. Berlin describes the position of the French-influenced Enlightenment and then discusses its German romantic opposite. I do not use “empirical” in the philosophical sense of the divide, between empirical Anglophone and non-empirical Continental philosophy.
  171. Declaration of Independence.
  172. Constitution of the United States, art. I, sec. 8.
  173. Saenz, Arlette. “Sen. Jim Inhofe Throws Snowball on Senate Floor in Attempt to Debunk Climate Change.” ABC News. 26 Feb. 2015, abcnews.go.com/Politics/sen-jim-inhofe-throws-snowball-senate-floor-attempt/story?id=29255635 (embedded video of Inhofe and the snowball).
  174. De Tocqueville, Alexis. Democracy in America. Edited and translated by Harvey C. Mansfield and Delba Winthrop. University of Chicago Press, 2000, ch. 10.
  175. United States Congress. Congressional Globe, vol. 27, p. 1693; 7 USC § 304.
  176. American Association for the Advancement of Science. “Historical Trends in Federal R&D.” Federal R&D as a share of discretionary and total budget, 1962–2016, www.aaas.org/page/historical-trends-federal-rd, and see also and compare with the citations provided for the figure in this chapter.
  177. White House, Council of Economic Advisers. “The 2016 Economic Report of the President.” In Economic Report of the President, Feb. 2016, p. 220 (internal citations omitted).
  178. Ibid., sec. 5.
  179. National Science Foundation. “R&D Recognized as Investment in U.S. GDP Statistics: GDP Increase Slightly Lowers R&D-to-GDP Ratio.” InfoBriefs, NSF 15-315, 30 Mar. 2015, www.nsf.gov/statistics/2015/nsf15315/. The American Association for the Advancement of Science and the BEA compile similar statistics showing the same trends.
  180. Pion, Georgine M., and Mark W. Lipsey. “Public Attitudes Toward Science and Technology: What Have the Surveys Told Us?” Public Opinion Quarterly, vol. 45, no. 3, 1981, pp. 303–316 and table 1.
  181. Ibid., table 1.
  182. Ibid., table 2. The wording on the survey changed over the years, and data are provided for the 1972–1976 surveys as worded. However, the overwhelmingly positive prior response to a (less nuanced) question, in combination with the rest of the data in this chapter, suggests that things took a turn in the early 1970s.
  183. Ibid., tables 3 and 309 (re: confidence in scientific establishment, support for basic research between the 1960s and 1970s); La Porte, Todd R., and Daniel Metlay. “Technology Observed: Attitudes of a Wary Public.” Science, 11 Apr. 1975, tables 3–4 (re: science’s ability to solve problems, from 1972 to 1974; sample based on California residents only).
  184. La Porte and Metlay, secs. 3–4.
  185. Ibid.
  186. Handler, Phillip. “Public Doubts About Science.” Science, vol. 208, no. 4448, 6 June 1980.
  187. Pew Research Center. “Americans, Politics and Science Issues.” 1 July 2015 (noting contemporary attitudes by cohort).
  188. National Science Foundation. “Science and Engineering Indicators, National Science Foundation 2014.” Appendix, tables 7–8 and ch. 7, generally, www.nsf.gov/statistics/2016/nsb20161/#/data. NSF decomposes the raw data, which can be found from the University of Chicago’s GSS, using indicators SOLARREV, EARTHSUN, etc. Only respondents who answered the heliocentric question correctly were asked the year-revolution question; those who answered the former incorrectly were coded as being wrong about the latter.
  189. Ibid.
  190. Ibid., ch. 7.
  191. Ibid., appendix, tables 2–17, 2–23, 2–33.
  192. Epstein, Jennifer. “Graduation Gaps for Science Majors.” Inside Higher Ed. 17 Feb. 2010, www.insidehighered.com/news/2010/02/17/stem; “Undergraduate Education, Enrollment, and Degrees in the United States.” Science and Engineering Indicators 2012, ch. 2, www.nsf.gov/statistics/seind12/c2/c2s2.htm; Anderson, Stuart. “The Importance of International Students to America.” National Foundation for American Policy. NEAP Policy Brief, July 2013, www.nfap.com/pdf/New%20NFAP%20Policy%20Brief%20The%20Importance%20of%20International%20Students%20to%20America,%20July%202013.pdf (compiling data from NSF); National Science Foundation. “Science and Engineering Indicators, National Science Foundation 2014.” Appendix, table 2-33 (available as download document).
  193. Google Ngram Viewer searches for “feel,” “how I feel,” and “I feel that.”
  194. Google Ngram Viewer search for “true.”
  195. Pew Research Center. “Public Trust in Government: 1958–2014.” 13 Nov. 2014, www.people-press.org/2014/11/13/public-trust-in-government/.
  196. Ibid.
  197. Burke, Edmund. “A Letter from Mr. Burke to a Member of the National Assembly; In Answer to Some Objections to his Book on French Affairs.” 19 Jan. 1791, metaphors.iath.virginia.edu/metaphors/20164 (excerpted); original available at books.google.com/books?id=L1wPAAAAQAAJ&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0#v=onepage&q=chain&f=false, pp. 68–69.
  198. Reagan, Ronald. 12 Aug. 1986, available in the Public Papers of the Presidents of the United States (June 28–Dec. 31, 1986) at 1081.
  199. Clymer, Adam. “M’Govern Asks Stand Against Tax-Cut Tide.” New York Times, 18 Jun. 1978.
  200. “Dietary Goals for the United States.” Prepared by the Staff of the Select Committee on Nutrition and Human Needs (known as the “McGovern Commission”), Feb. 1977, pp. 1–2. Ninety-Fifth United States Congress, 1st Session.
  201. “Vice President Spiro Agnew Speech.” The Pacifica Radio/UC Berkeley. Social Activism Sound Recording Project. Houston, Texas, 22 May 1970, lib.berkeley.edu/MRC/pacificaviet/agnewtranscript.html.
  202. Novak, Michael. “Reconsidering Vatican II.” CatholiCity. 20 Apr. 2010.
  203. Newport, Frank. “Catholics Similar to Mainstream on Abortion, Stem-Cells.” Gallup. 30 Mar. 2009, www.gallup.com/poll/117154/catholics-similar-mainstream-abortion-stem-cells.aspx. Catholics who regularly attend church are more orthodox, but substantial minorities still hold more liberal, heterodox views on many matters.
  204. “Pontifical Council for Legislative Text” (approved by Benedict XVI). 13 Mar. 2006, www.vatican.va/roman_curia/pontifical_councils/intrptxt/documents/rc_pc_intrptxt_doc_20060313_actus-formalis_en.html.
  205. “A Church Divided: Ruling Ends Va.’s Episcopal Battle.” NPR. All Things Considered. 10 Apr. 2012, www.npr.org/2012/04/10/150351713/a-church-divided-ruling-ends-va-s-episcopal-battle.
  206. Montague, John. “The Law and Financial Transparency in Churches: Reconsidering the form 990 Exemption.” Cardozo Law Review, vol. 35, no. 203, 2013, www.cardozolawreview.com/content/35-1/MONTAGUE.35.1.pdf.
  207. “Do All Dogs Really Go To Heaven?” CBN. www1.cbn.com/700club/do-all-dogs-really-go-heaven.
  208. Malachi 3:10 (King James Version).
    Chapter 6: Disco and the Roots of Neoliberalism
  209. Roosevelt, Franklin D. Second Inaugural Address. 20 Jan. 1937, http://avalon.law.yale.edu/20th_century/froos2.asp.
  210. Von Mises, Ludwig. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. The Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998, at 874. The German edition appeared in 1940, the English edition, in 1949.
  211. Von Mises, Ludwig. Liberalism: In the Classical Tradition, ch. 11, Mises Institute, mises.org/library/liberalism-classical-tradition/html/p/30.
  212. Say, Jean-Baptiste. A Treatise on Political Economy. See also Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations (note, however, that Smith, while favoring a limited role for government and emphasizing the market’s superior ability to organize itself, did endorse certain specific roles for the government, like the post, and the encouragement of certain industries—these specifics have now been lost to the generality of Smith’s Invisible Hand).
  213. Harris, Ethan S. Ben Bernanke’s Fed: The Federal Reserve After Greenspan. Harvard Business Review Press. 15 July 2008, ch. 12. There are several similar, but slightly different versions of this quote floating around, but the substance is always the same.
  214. “Statement of Aims.” The Mont Pelerin Society. www.montpelerin.org/statement-of-aims/.
  215. “Mont Pelerin Society Directory 2010.” Re-created by DeSmogBlog. www.desmogblog.com/sites/beta.desmogblog.com/files/Mont%20Pelerin%20Society%20Directory%202010.pdf.
  216. “‘Goldwater Girl’: Putting Context to a Resurfaced Hillary Clinton Interview.” NPR. 26 Mar. 2016, www.npr.org/2016/03/26/471958017/-goldwater-girl-putting-context-to-a-resurfaced-hillary-clinton-interview?version=meter+at+7&module=meterLinks&pgtype=article&contentId=&mediaId=&referrer=https%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.com%2F&priority=true&action=click&contentCollection=meter-links-click.
  217. Goldwater, Barry. The Conscience of a Conservative. E-book ed., Start Publishing, 2012, ch. 2, generally, and pp. 85–86.
  218. Ibid., pp. 86–87.
  219. Ibid., p. 88.
  220. Ibid., p. 98.
  221. Ibid., p.100.
  222. Chomsky, Noam. “Richard Nixon Was ‘Last Liberal President.’” Huffington Post. 21 Feb. 2014, www.huffingtonpost.com/2014/02/21/noam-chomsky-richard-nixon_n_4832847.html.
  223. Bachman, Helena. “Global First? Every Swiss Could Be Guaranteed $2,600 a Month Tax-Free.” USA Today, 6 May 2016, www.usatoday.com/story/news/world/2016/05/05/switzerland-referendom-monthly-income-tax-free/83940610/; “Switzerland’s Voters Reject Basic Income Plan.” BBC. 5 June 2016, www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-36454060.
  224. Parker, Richard. John Kenneth Galbraith: His Life, His Politics, His Economics. 1st ed., University of Chicago Press, 1 Aug. 2006, p. 501; Perlman, Rick. Nixonland: The Rise of a President and the Fracturing of America. Scribner, 14 Apr. 2009, p. 710.
  225. FRED, UNRATE.
  226. Mayer, Gerald. “Union Membership Trends in the United States.” CRS Report for Congress. 31 Aug. 2004, digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1176&context=key_workplace generally and at Appendix A (referring to “employed” workers; the same trends are true based on other subcategories with minor differences in absolute levels); US Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (hereinafter “BLS”). “Union members—2015.” Press Release. 28 Jan. 2016, www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/union2.pdf.
  227. FRED, UNRATE, FPCPITOTLZGUSA (World Bank); CPI (BEA).
  228. US Census, Income and Poverty Reports (various years); BEA, inflation indicators; author’s calculations. See also “Trends in the Distribution of Household Income between 1979 and 2007,” Congressional Budget Office, October 2011. The BLS also decomposes average hourly earnings overall and by sector and these show the same trends.
  229. “President Gerald R. Ford’s Address to a Joint Session of Congress on the Economy.” Gerald R. Ford Presidential Library & Museum. www.fordlibrarymuseum.gov/library/speeches/740121.asp.
  230. Mieczkowski, Yanek. Gerald Ford and the Challenges of the 1970s. University Press of Kentucky, 22 Apr. 2005, p. 131; see also Birnbaum, Jeffrey H. “Ford’s Economic Record Belies His Reputation.” Washington Post. 28 Dec. 2006, www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/12/27/AR2006122701580.html.
  231. White House, Office of Management and Budget. “Historical Tables.” Table 1.2, www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals. (2014–2016).
  232. Carter, Jimmy. “‘Crisis of Confidence’ Speech.” Miller Center. Transcript. 15 July 1979, millercenter.org/president/speeches/speech-3402.
    Chapter 7: The Boomer Ascendancy
  233. Hamilton, Alexander, James Madison, John Jay, Ian Shapiro (ed.). The Federalist Papers. No. 47 at 245. New Haven, CT: 2009. Madison was talking about separation of institutional powers. Asking whether Madison would have viewed institutional dominance by Boomers as being more parallel to his thinking in the Federalist Papers or A Candid State of Parties is probably too pedantic for an epigraph (or even an endnote); suffice it to say, I doubt he would have been thrilled by the Boomers.
  234. US Census. “Historical National Population, Intercensal Estimates from 2000 to 2010, Population Estimates Program for 2013”; CDC, “Death Rates, CDC-NCHS Live Births from 1909 to 2003”; author’s calculations; supra chapter 1, note 4.
  235. US Department of Health and Human Services, CDC, Population Statistics, “Resident population, by age, sex, race, and Hispanic origin: United States, selected years 1950–2013”, www.cdc.gov/nchs/hus/hispanic.htm#population (accessed for 2013 data); supra note 2.
  236. Neale, Thomas H. “The Eighteen Year Old Vote: The Twenty-Sixth Amendment and Subsequent Voting Rates of Newly Enfranchised Age Groups.” Report No. 83-103. Library of Congress, Congressional Research Service, 20 May 1983, digital.library.unt.edu/ark:/67531/metacrs8805/m1/1/high_res_d/83-103GOV_1983May20.pdf. The four states with sub-twenty-one voting ages were Georgia, Kentucky, Alaska (nineteen-year-old vote), and Hawaii (twenty-year-old vote)—and only two of these states had substantial electorates.
  237. US Census, “Current Estimates Data” Population Estimates, 2015, www.census.gov/popest/data/index.html; CDC. “Live Births, Birth Rates, and Fertility Rates, by Race: 1909–2003.” Vital Statistics of the United States, Table 1-1, www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/statab/natfinal2003.annvol1_01.pdf; US Census. “Death Rates by Age, Sex, and Race: 1950 to 2008.” Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2011, table 110, 2012, census.gov/library/publications/2011/compendia/statab/131ed/tables/12s0110.pdf; author’s calculations.
  238. Kennedy, Edward M. “Voting Age to 18 Testimony Before the Senate Subcommittee on Constitutional Amendments.” 9 Mar. 1970, tedkennedy.org/ownwords/event/voting_age.
  239. I’m synthesizing the results of two surveys here, which is not best practice, but given the vast gulf between popular and political knowledge, a gap that’s appeared repeatedly across many polls, the point stands. University of Pennsylvania, Annenberg Public Policy Center. “Americans Know Surprisingly Little About Their Government, Survey Finds.” 17 Sept. 2014, cdn.annenbergpublicpolicycenter.org/wp-content/uploads/Civics-survey-press-release-09-17-2014-for-PR-Newswire.pdf; Pew Research Center. “What Americans Know: 1989–2007: Public Knowledge of Current Affairs Little Changed by News and Information Revolutions.” 15 Apr. 2007, www.people-press.org/files/legacy-pdf/319.pdf.
  240. Supra notes 2–3.
  241. Ibid.
  242. Nixon, Richard. “Letter to House Leaders Supporting a Constitutional Amendment to Lower the Voting Age.” The American Presidency Project. 27 Apr. 1970, www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=2487; Berman, Ari. “What the Supreme Court Doesn’t Understand about the Voting Rights Act.” Nation. 25 June 2013, www.thenation.com/article/what-supreme-court-doesnt-understand-about-voting-rights-act/.
  243. US House of Representatives, History, Art & Archives. “The 26th Amendment.” 1 July 1971, history.house.gov/Historical-Highlights/1951-2000/The-26th-Amendment/; Senate. Journal of the Senate. 92nd Congress, 1st session, 1971. S. S.J. Res. 7/ 65 Stat. 710, 1971.
  244. “Ratification of Constitutional Amendments.” U.S. Constitution Online, usconstitution.net/constamrat.html.
  245. Fish, Eric S. “The Twenty-Sixth Amendment Enforcement Power.” Yale Law Journal, vol. 121 no. 5 (Mar. 2012), pp. 1222–1224.
  246. Ghitza, Yair, and Andrew Gelman. “The Great Society, Reagan’s Revolution and Generations of Presidential Voting.” Working Paper. 7 July 2014, p. 17; and Gallup. “Election Polls—Vote By Groups, 1968–1972.” See also infra note 21.
  247. Balz, Dan. “Karl Rove—The Strategist.” Washington Post. 23 July 1999, www.washingtonpost.com/wp-srv/politics/campaigns/wh2000/stories/rove072399.htm.
  248. Ghitza and Gelman. “The Great Society, Reagan’s Revolution and Generations of Presidential Voting” (working paper); see infra note 21 for a discussion of this work.
  249. Toomey, Traci L., et al. “The Age-21 Minimum Legal Drinking Age: A Case Study Linking Past and Current Debates.” Addiction, vol. 104, no. 12, Dec. 2009, pp. 1958–1965 (the last state to lower its drinking age, Oklahoma, hewed an odd course: it allowed for the sale of “non-intoxicating” beer of under 3.2 percent alcohol content to women under twenty-one but not men; the Supreme Court found this constituted gender discrimination and banned the practice); Craig v. Boren, 429 US at 190–191 (1976).
  250. 23 USC 158 (1984).
  251. See infra note 23.
  252. Based on author’s calculations using an API pull from www.govtrack.us and comparison to Congress.gov, https://www.congress.gov/search?q=%7B%22source%22%3A%22members%22%7D. The chart’s underlying data, from the API pull, calculates membership based on election results and the start of a Congressional term. Small variances are produced by resignations, deaths, and other changes to the House intraterm, but these are minor and often tended to increase the number of Boomers, as in 2008 where the replacements added to the net Boomer count. Excluded from these calculations are non-voting members of the House representing the District of Columbia and the territories. See also the footnote to this paragraph regarding my treatment of term dates of a given Congress. In general, Boomer shares of government cited in this book derive from the sources and methods noted here, usually the API pulls.
  253. Ghitza and Gelman. See also the interactive tool available on the NY Times website, using the same data at: http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2014/07/08/upshot/how-the-year-you-were-born-influences-your-politics.html. Ghitza and Gelman use presidential approval ratings as a proxy for party affiliation, and model cumulative preferences, and how a person born in a given year might vote in an “average” election. The Democratic sub-cohort of 1947–1954 is only about a third of the Boomer population and the rest of the Boomers drift Republican, pushing the whole generation into Republican territory. Exit polling data is another way to break out political preferences, but these surveys tend to clump age groups (e.g., 30–44) in large buckets that make it difficult to perform a continuous analysis. In general, the Boomers tended to favor the winning candidate (who won in large part due to Boomer electoral strength). From 1988–2008, presidential elections for Boomer cohorts either trended Republican or where a Democrat had a plurality, they tended to favor the Democrat somewhat more weakly than younger groups, and in very close elections like 2000, Boomer deviations had a significant impact. The exit poll data are for all people in the age bracket; stripping out the decisively Democratic vote of certain groups (like blacks) tends to push white Boomers into even greater deviation from younger groups in a Rightward tilt. Best, Samuel J., Brian S. Krueger, Exit Polls: Surveying the American Electorate, 1972–2010. Sage/CQ Press, Los Angeles (2012); author’s calculations. The data for House elections is highly varied, though Boomers appeared to be the most Republican groups in certain critical House elections, like those of 1994 and 2010. Again, the absence of continuous and granular data over long periods, and the limited number of elections and often vivid comparisons between candidates (which Ghitza and Gelman tried to factor out), make it harder to draw robust inferences from exit polls. There does seem to be a tilt, and many authors do believe it is significant. In the end, the actual party affiliation matters less than the policies pursued by a given politician, which is the subject of the next chapters. The fact of a secret ballot (a definite social good) means that it will always be impossible to really know how anyone voted, and this may be a particular problem in self-reported data like exit polls from sociopaths prone to deception.
    Chapter 8: Taxes
  254. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013.” 8 June 2016, pp. 3, 18–19.
  255. Oxford English Dictionary. Online edition.
  256. US Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service. “IRS Proposes New Registration, Testing and Continuing Education Requirements for Tax Return Preparers Not Already Subject to Oversight.” 3 Nov. 2014, www.irs.gov/uac/IRS-Proposes-New-Registration,-Testing-and-Continuing-Education-Requirements-for-Tax-Return-Preparers-Not-Already-Subject-to-Oversight.
  257. Grieder, William. “Rolling Back the 20th Century: The Right-Wing Ideologues Are Dead Serious About Dismantling Government.” Nation. 24 Apr. 2003, www.thenation.com/article/rolling-back-20th-century/.
  258. Good, Chris. “Norquist’s Tax Pledge: What It Is and How It Started.” ABC News. 26 Nov. 2012, abcnews.go.com/blogs/politics/2012/11/norquists-tax-pledge-what-it-is-and-how-it-started/; “Federal Taxpayer Protection Pledge Questions and Answers.” Americans for Tax Reform. 1 June 2011, www.atr.org/federal-taxpayer-protection-questions-answers-a6204.
  259. Constitution of the United States. art. I, sec. 2.
  260. “Fact Sheet, 100-Year Tax History: The Length and Legacy of Tax Law.” CCH. www.cch.com/wbot2013/factsheet.pdf (a summary by a major publisher of the tax codes); The Bible: Authorized King James Version. Edited by Robert Carroll and Stephen Prickett. Oxford University Press. 15 May 2008; Amazon. www.amazon.com/Bible-Authorized-Version-Oxford-Classics/dp/0199535949/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&qid=1452610777&sr=8-1&keywords=oxford+king+james+bible.
  261. Fraser, C. Gerald. “Writers and Editors to Defy Tax in War Protest.” New York Times, 31 Jan. 1968, p. 2.
  262. Writers and Editors War Tax Protest, http://jfk.hood.edu/Collection/Weisberg%20Subject%20Index%20Files/W%20Disk/Writers%20and%20Editors%20Protest/Item%2002.pdf (the “pledge”).
  263. “Joan Baez Declares War on IRS.” Desert Sun, no. 282, 30 June 1964, cdnc.ucr.edu/cgi-bin/cdnc?a=d&d=DS19640630.2.32.
  264. Schulz, Kathryn. “Pond Scum.” New Yorker, 19 Oct. 2015, www.newyorker.com/magazine/2015/10/19/pond-scum; Brooks, Rebecca Beatrice. “Henry David Thoreau Arrested for Nonpayment of Poll Tax.” History of Massachusetts, 14 July 2012, historyofmassachusetts.org/henry-david-thoreau-arrested-for-nonpayment-of-poll-tax/.
  265. Internal Revenue Service. “U.S. Individual Income Tax.” Statistics of Income Tax, Historical Table 23, May 2016, www.irs.gov/uac/soi-tax-stats-historical-table-23. For an Excel-ready summary, see Tax Foundation. “Federal Individual Income Tax Rates History: Nominal Dollar: Income Years 1913–2013.” taxfoundation.org/sites/default/files/docs/fed_individual_rate_history_nominal.pdf (a tabular presentation of tax brackets without editorial gloss).
  266. Jacobson, Darien B., Brian G. Raub, and Barry W. Johnson. “The Estate Tax: Ninety Years and Counting.” Statistics of Income Bulletin 27.1 (2007): 118-28, https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/07sumbul.pdf.
  267. Social Security Administration. “Research Note #12: Taxation of Social Security Benefits.” Agency History. www.ssa.gov/history/taxationofbenefits.html. See also Social Security Amendments of 1983, Pub Law 98-21, enacted 20 April 1983 (applying to the first tax year after 1983—i.e., 1984).
  268. Internal Revenue Service. “U.S. Individual Income Tax.” Statistics of Income Tax, Historical Table 23, May 2016, www.irs.gov/uac/soi-tax-stats-historical-table-23.
  269. Ventry, Dennis J. Jr. “The Accidental Deduction: A History and Critique of the Tax Subsidy for Mortgage Interest.” Duke Law Review, vol. 73, no. 1, 2010, p. 275.
  270. Ippolito, Dennis S. Deficits, Debt and the New Politics of Tax Policy. Cambridge University Press, Nov. 2012, p. 167. For a general discussion of Bush I’s tax policies, see Brownlee, W. Elliot, Federal Taxation in America: A History, 3d ed., Cambridge University Press, 2016, pp. 210–220.
  271. Ippolito, p. 167. (internal cites and quotes omitted).
  272. Ibid.
  273. Schmalz, Jeffrey, “The 1992 Election: The Nation’s Voters: Clinton Carves a Wide Path Deep into Reagan Country.” New York Times, 4 Nov. 1992, www.nytimes.com/1992/11/04/nyregion/1992-election-nation-s-voters-clinton-carves-wide-path-deep-into-reagan-country.html.
  274. Omnibus Reconciliation Act of 1993, PL 103-66; Brownlee, at ch. 8. See also for a more readable history of rates: Tax Foundation. “U.S. Federal Individual Income Tax Rates History, 1862–2013.” taxfoundation.org/sites/default/files/docs/fed_individual_rate_history_nominal.pdf.
  275. Ippolito, p. 171.
  276. Purdum, Todd S. “Clinton Angers Friend and Foe in Tax Remark.” New York Times, 19 Oct. 1995, www.nytimes.com/1995/10/19/us/clinton-angers-friend-and-foe-in-tax-remark.html; Richter, Paul. “Clinton Apologies May Not Be Sorry Move, Analysts Say: Politics: Official Washington Is Reacting Negatively to the President’s Statements, but the Tactic Has Worked in the Past, Observers Note.” Los Angeles Times, 4 Nov. 1995, articles.latimes.com/1995-11-04/news/mn-64654_1_official-washington.
  277. Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, PL 105–34.
  278. Ibid.
  279. Economic Growth and Tax Reconciliation Relief Act of 2001, PL 107–16.
  280. Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003, PL 108–27.
  281. Ibid.
  282. Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010, PL 111-312.
  283. American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012, PL 112–140.
  284. Ibid.
  285. Ibid.
  286. Ibid. See also for a summary, Sullivan, Paul. “The End of a Decade of Uncertainty over Gift and Estate Taxes.” New York Times, 4 Jan. 2013, www.nytimes.com/2013/01/05/your-money/fiscal-deal-ends-decade-of-uncertainty-over-gift-and-estate-taxes.html.
  287. The property-tax limiting Proposition 13 entered the California Constitution as Art. 13A.
  288. “How Proposition 13 Changed California Politics.” Contra Consta Bee. contracostabee.com/proposition-13-california-politics/; “Governor’s Budget Summary—2016-2017”; California Budget. www.ebudget.ca.gov/2016-17/pdf/BudgetSummary/Introduction.pdf; Steinhauer, Jennifer. “In Budget Deal, California Shuts $41 Billion Gap.” New York Times, 19 Feb. 2009, www.nytimes.com/2009/02/20/us/20california.html; “Two Steps Back: Should California Cut Its Way to a Balanced Budget?” The California Budget Project. Feb. 2008. www.sdgrantmakers.org/Portals/0/PastPrograms/CBPTwoStepsBack.pdf.
  289. Office of Management and Budget. “Corporate Income Taxes.” Budget of the U.S. Government: Historical Tables, table 2.2, www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/budget/fy2017/assets/hist.pdf.; FRED, CP (BEA); author’s calculations.
  290. Marr, Chuck, and Cecile Murray. “IRS Funding Cuts Compromise Taxpayer Service and Weaken Enforcement,” updated 4 April 2016. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, http://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/6-25-14tax.pdf; Letter from former IRS commissioners to the Senate and House Committees on Appropriations, 2015, taxprof.typepad.com/files/former-irs-comissioners-letter-on-agency-budget.pdf; Johnston, David Cay. “Honey, They Shrunk the IRS.” Reuters, 17 Jan. 2012, blogs.reuters.com/david-cay-johnston/2012/01/17/honey-they-shrunk-the-irs (noting that the “likelihood of a big company being audited has plummeted 50 percentage points from 72 percent in 1990 to 22 percent in 2010”); Bischoff, Bill, MarketWatch. “Worried about being audited by the IRS? Here are your chances.” MarketWatch, 29 Jan. 2016 (part of a series from MarketWatch on this subject, including a prior article dated December 15, 2015).
  291. Rubin, Richard. “IRS to Hire Up to 700 Enforcement Workers.” Wall Street Journal, 3 May 2016, www.wsj.com/articles/irs-to-hire-up-to-700-enforcement-workers-1462302623.
  292. “Tax Gap Estimates for Tax Years 2008–2010.” Internal Revenue Service, April 2016.
  293. Quoted in Bartlett, Bruce. “The New Republican Tax Policy.” New York Times, Economix (blog), 20 Nov. 2012, economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/11/20/the-new-republican-tax-policy/.
  294. Dreyfuss, Bob. “Grover Norquist: ‘Field Marshal’ of the Bush Plan.” Nation, 26 Apr. 2001, www.thenation.com/article/grover-norquist-field-marshal-bush-plan/.
  295. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Synopses, No. 24 (2011).
  296. E.g., supra note 1 at 22.
  297. “Total Government Receipts in Absolute Amounts and as Percentages of GDP: 1948–2015.” Office of Management and Budget, 2016, https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals.
  298. Ibid.; author’s calculations.
  299. Ibid.
    Chapter 9: Debt and Deficits
  300. US Government Accountability Office. “Bureau of the Fiscal Service’s Fiscal Years 2015 and 2014 Schedules of Federal Debts.” GAO, Report to the Secretary of the Treasury, Nov. 2015, www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/feddebt/feddebt_ann2015.pdf.
  301. Smith, Robert. “When the U.S. Paid Off the Entire National Debt (And Why It Didn’t Last).” NPR, 15 Apr. 2011, www.npr.org/sections/money/2011/04/15/135423586/when-the-u-s-paid-off-the-entire-national-debt-and-why-it-didnt-last; Faber, Harold. “There Was a Surplus, Once.” New York Times, 6 Feb. 1986, www.nytimes.com/1986/02/06/us/there-was-a-surplus-once.html; Meacham, Jon. American Lion: Andrew Jackson in the White House, reprinted ed., Random House Trade Paperbacks, 30 Apr. 2009, ch. 28, p. 298.
  302. US Department of the Treasury, Treasury Direct. “Historical Debt Outstanding—Annual 1790–1849,” www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/histdebt/histdebt_histo1.htm.
  303. FRED, GFDEGQ188S (original sources: FRED and OMB). An overview can be found from the CBO, infra note 5.
  304. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “The Budget and Economic Outlook 2016–2026.” Jan. 2016, p. 1; US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “The 2016 Budget Outlook”; Presentation by Keith Hall at the Peter G. Peterson Foundation’s 2016 Fiscal Summit, 11 May 2016, p. 15; US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “2015 Long-Term Budget Outlook.” June 2015, pp. 11 and 79–80, www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/114th-congress-2015-2016/reports/50250-LongTermBudgetOutlook-4.pdf. The first two cites show that the point when the war debt threshold will be surpassed has advanced from 2040 into the 2030s (based on changes in projections from 2015 to 2016).
  305. Jefferson, Thomas. “Letter to James Madison.” 1789, Memorial ed. 7:455; Jefferson, Thomas. “Letter to A. L. C. Destutt de Tracy.” 1820, Ford ed. 10:175.
  306. Hamilton, Alexander. “Letter to Robert Morris.” 30 Apr. 1781, Founders Online, National Archives, last modified October 5, 2016, http://founders.archives.gov/documents/Hamilton/01-02-02-1167. (Original source: The Papers of Alexander Hamilton, vol. 2, 1779–1781, ed. Harold C. Syrett. New York: Columbia University Press, 1961, pp. 604–635.) Hamilton, Alexander. “Report on Public Credit.” Reports of the Secretary of the Treasury of the United States, vol. 1, Blair & Rives, 1837, p. 27 (original statement made January 1790).
  307. Nietzsche, Friedrich. “On The Genealogy of Morality.” Second Essay.
  308. Schama, Simon. Citizens: A Chronicle of the French Revolution. Vintage Books, Mar. 1990, p. 65.
  309. Ibid., p. 66.
  310. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (hereinafter “OECD”), OECD Data. “General Government Debt.” data.oecd.org/gga/general-government-debt.htm. It’s impossible to precisely know or compare China’s debt-to-GDP ratio because of government manipulations and government ownership of industries, but Chinese debt levels were and are high.
  311. US Government Accountability Office. “Bureau of the Fiscal Service’s Fiscal Years 2015 and 2014 Schedules of Federal Debts.” Report to the Secretary of the Treasury, Nov. 2015, www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/feddebt/feddebt_ann2015.pdf (for fiscal years 2014–2015).
  312. Constitution of the United States, art. I, sec. 10, and Tenth Amendment. States cannot abrogate their obligations, and declaring federal bankruptcy would put states under the jurisdiction of a federal judge, violating the sovereignty provisions of the Tenth Amendment.
  313. Detrixhe, John. “U.S. Loses AAA Rating at S&P on Concern Debt Cuts Deficient.” Bloomberg, 6 Aug. 2011, www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2011-08-06/u-s-credit-rating-cut-by-s-p-for-first-time-on-deficit-reduction-accord.
  314. Office of Management and Budget. “Federal Debt at the End of the Year: 1940–2021.” 2016, www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals.
  315. Bartlett, Bruce. “Starve the Beast.” Independent Review, vol. 12, no. 1, Summer 2007, www.independent.org/pdf/tir/tir_12_01_01_bartlett.pdf. Bartlett was first an assistant to Jack Kemp (one of the co-sponsors of the major 1981 cut) and then a Treasury Department official.
  316. Blustein, Paul. “Recent Budget Battles Leave the Basic Tenets of Welfare State Intact.” Wall Street Journal, 21 Oct. 1985.
  317. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2002–2011.” Jan. 2001, xiii, summary table 1, et seq.
  318. Ibid.; and US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2014–2024.” Table H-1; author’s calculations.
  319. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “Updated Budget Projections: 2016–2026.” Mar. 2016, table 2.
  320. White House, Office of Management and Budget. Historical Debt Tables, table 7.1, www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals (for fiscal 2015).
  321. Ibid.; see also US Government Accountability Office. “Bureau of the Fiscal Service’s Fiscal Years 2015 and 2014 Schedules of Federal Debts.”
  322. White House, Office of Management and Budget. Historical Debt Tables; see also US Department of the Treasury, Treasury Direct. “Historical Debt Outstanding—Annual 2000–2005,” www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/histdebt/histdebt_histo5.htm.
  323. Library of Congress, Congressional Research Service. Debt Ceiling History; see also US Government Accountability Office. “Bureau of the Fiscal Service’s Fiscal Years 2015 and 2014 Schedules of Federal Debts.”
  324. Social Security Administration. “Frequently Asked Questions About the Social Security Trust Funds.” Questions 4 and 7 (noting that the “cash exchanged for the securities [of the Trust Fund] goes into the general fund of the Treasury and is indistinguishable from other cash in the general fund”), www.ssa.gov/OACT/ProgData/fundFAQ.html#&a0=6.
  325. Ibid.; and Social Security Administration. “Social Security Board of Trustees: Trust Fund Reserve Gains One Year for Projected Depletion Date.” Press release, 22 July 2015, www.ssa.gov/news/#/post/7-2015-1.
  326. Social Security Administration. “Frequently Asked Questions About the Social Security Trust Funds.”
  327. US Government Accountability Office. “Bureau of the Fiscal Service’s Fiscal Years 2015 and 2014 Schedules of Federal Debts.”
  328. The Board of Trustees, Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Funds. The 2015 Annual Report of the Boards of Trustees of the Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Funds 2015 (hereinafter “Medicare Trustees Report 2015”), p. 26, Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services, www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/ReportsTrustFunds/Downloads/TR2015.pdf. See the discussion in Chapters 12 and 13.
  329. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. “Federal Reserve Banks Combined Financial Statements: As of and for the Years Ended December 31, 2015 and 2014 and Independent Auditors’ Report,” www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/combinedfinstmt2015.pdf.
  330. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. “Financial Accounts of the United States.” 10 Mar. 2016, table D3.
  331. US Department of the Treasury. “Recovery Act,” www.treasury.gov/initiatives/recovery/Pages/babs.aspx.
  332. US Department of the Treasury. “Treasury Analysis of Build America Bonds Insurance and Savings,” p. 3, www.treasury.gov/initiatives/recovery/Documents/BABs%20Report.pdf.
  333. Federal Reserve. “Debt Outstanding by Sector.” Financial Accounts of the United States, table D3, September 2016. www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/z1.pdf.; US Treasury. “Federal Debt.” Treasury Bulletin, Table FD-1, September 2016. www.fiscal.treasury.gov/fsreports/rpt/treasBulletin/current.htm.; author’s calculations. See also Chapter 12. The speculative items are all important, but they are contingent and will be paid over different time horizons, so I’ve excluded them—though they, and the additional ~2–3 percent of GDP added to the debt annually (via the deficit)—will all have to paid by the young.
  334. US Department of the Treasury. Fiscal Year 2015 Financial Report of the United States Government, 2016, p. 19.
  335. Wessel, David, and Thomas T. Vogel Jr. “Arcane World of Bonds Is Guide and Beacon to a Populist President.” Wall Street Journal, 25 Feb 1993, A1.
  336. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. Selected Interest Rates (Daily)—H.15; US Department of Labor. Bureau of Labor Statistics. “Consumer Price Index.”
  337. US Department of the Treasury, Treasury Direct. “Interest Expense on the Debt Outstanding,” treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/ir/ir_expense.htm.
  338. US Department of the Treasury, Office of Debt Management. “Treasury Presentation to TBAC,” www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/quarterly-refunding/Documents/November%202014%20QRCombined%20Charges%20for%20Archives.pdf.
  339. See supra notes 38–40; author’s calculations (based on Treasury data and ten-year yields).
  340. Appelbaum, Binyamin. “Donald Trump’s Idea to Cut National Debt: Get Creditors to Accept Less.” New York Times, 6 May 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/05/07/us/politics/donald-trumps-idea-to-cut-national-debt-get-creditors-to-accept-less.html?_r=0.
  341. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors “Financial Accounts of the United States,” 10 Mar. 2016, table D3; Federal Reserve Statistical Release, G.19, Consumer Credit, released 6 May 2016.
  342. US Federal Reserve Statistical Release. “Financial Accounts of the United States,” 10 Mar. 2016, table D3.
  343. Federal Judicial Center. “Bankruptcy Cases.” www.fjc.gov/history/caseload.nsf/page/caseloads_bankruptcy; US Census. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1965, part II, no. 3 (defines adults by excluding population nineteen and under).
  344. Federal Judicial Center. “Bankruptcy Cases”; US Census. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1999, sec. 1, no. 14 (defines adults by excluding population nineteen and under).
  345. Eder, Steve, and Michael Barbaro. “Marco Rubio’s Career Bedeviled by Financial Struggles.” New York Times, 9 June 2015, www.nytimes.com/2015/06/10/us/politics/marco-rubio-finances-debt-loans-credit.html.
  346. Rubin, Richard, and John McCormick. “Even 40,000 Scott Walkers Aren’t as Wealthy as Donald Trump.” Bloomberg, 3 Aug. 2015, www.bloomberg.com/politics/articles/2015-08-03/even-40-000-scott-walkers-aren-t-as-wealthy-as-donald-trump; Jacobs, Harrison. “Scott Walker has tens of thousands of dollars’ worth of credit-card debt.” Business Insider, 3 Aug. 2015, www.businessinsider.com/scott-walker-has-tens-of-thousands-of-dollars-worth-of-credit-card-debt-2015-8.
  347. Topaz, Jonathan, and Kristen East. “Bernie Sanders’ Wife Accounts for All His Reported Assets.” Politico, 16 July 2015, www.politico.com/story/2015/07/bernie-sanders-wife-accounts-for-reported-assets-120261; Gaudiano, Nicole. “Credit Card Debt a Regular Feature on Sanders’ Finance Reports.” USA Today, 12 June 2015.
  348. McIntire, Mike. “Ted Cruz Didn’t Report Goldman Sachs Loan in a Senate Race.” New York Times, 13 Jan. 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/01/14/us/politics/ted-cruz-wall-street-loan-senate-bid-2012.html.
  349. “A Chance to Reset the Republican Race.” Editorial. New York Times, 30 Jan. 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/01/31/opinion/sunday/a-chance-to-reset-the-republican-race.html?action=click&pgtype=Homepage&clickSource=story-heading&module=opinion-c-col-top-region&region=opinion-c-col-top-region&WT.nav=opinion-c-col-top-region&_r=1; Niquette, Mark. “John Kasich’s Lehman Days Create Rorshach Test for Viewing His Career.” Bloomberg, 9 July 2015, www.bloomberg.com/politics/articles/2015-07-09/john-kasich-s-lehman-days-create-rorshach-test-for-viewing-his-career; Lee, MJ. “John Kasich’s Wall Street Ties Could Haunt 2016 Bid.” CNN, 8 June 2015, www.cnn.com/2015/06/08/politics/john-kasich-2016-lehman-brothers-wall-street/index.html.
    Chapter 10: Indefinitely Deferred Maintenance
  350. DSM-V, pp. 659–61.
  351. Oxford English Dictionary. Online edition.
  352. BEA. NIPA tables, 2014, sec. 1, 5. Other countries have different accounting mechanisms, but the general point remains and is reinforced by a drive down any European or Japanese freeway.
  353. Ibid. (text); Wessel, David. “Spending on Our Crumbling Infrastructure.” Wall Street Journal. 10 Mar. 2015. http://blogs.wsj.com/washwire/2015/03/10/spending-on-our-crumbling-infrastructure/ (footnote). See also note 12 regarding Summers.
  354. Bowe, Rebecca, and Lisa Pickoff-White. “Five Years after Deadly San Bruno Explosion: Are We Safer?” KQED News. The California Report, 8 Sept. 2015, ww2.kqed.org/news/2015/09/08/five-years-after-deadly-san-bruno-explosion-are-we-safer; Rawlings, Nate. “Joe Biden Says NYC Airport Like ‘Some 3rd-World Country.’” Time, 7 Feb. 2014.
  355. American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, 2013, pp. 11–12. Like all rigorous analyses, ASCE’s methodology and assessments have changed somewhat over time, but the grades across time are clearly designed to be comparative.
  356. Ibid., p. 67.
  357. Ibid.
  358. Ibid.; see also “About the Report Card: Methodology.” www.infrastructurereportcard.org/a/#p/about-the-report-card/methodology.
  359. American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, pp. 65–67; author’s calculations.
  360. Bivens, Josh. “The Short-and Long-Term Impacts of Infrastructure Investments on U.S. Employment and Economic Activity.” Economic Policy Institute. Briefing paper, 374, 1 July 2014, p. 19 et seq. (citing CBO, CEA, Moody’s, and its own research); International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook. Oct. 2014, ch. 3, p. 82.
  361. Summers, Lawrence H. “The Age of Secular Stagnation: What It Is and What to Do About It.” Foreign Affairs, March–April 2016, www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2016-02-15/age-secular-stagnation.
  362. US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. “Highway Statistics 2014.” tables VM-1, MF-2, www.fhwa.dot.gov/policyinformation/statistics/2014/. (Though the report’s title says 2014, the data are from 2015.)
  363. Author’s calculations based on, for example, US Department of Energy (DOE), Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy (EERE), Transportation Energy Data Book (TEDB), June 2011, table 1.12. “2015 Urban Mobility Score Card.” Texas A&M Transportation Institute, Aug. 2015, Ex. 1 et seq., d2dtl5nnlpfr0r.cloudfront.net/tti.tamu.edu/documents/mobility-scorecard-2015-wappx.pdf. The congestion costs alone are about $160 billion in fuel and time, with accidents and other effects adding even more.
  364. Federation of Tax Administrators. “State Motor Fuel Taxes: Gasoline.” Apr. 2016, (figures obtained by subtracting noted state delta of 5 cpg 2015–2016). Gas taxes include smaller, transport-related items like a contribution to mass transit, funding for leaking containers, etc.
  365. Auxier, Richard. “Reforming State Gas Taxes.” Tax Policy Center, 6 Nov. 2014, taxpolicycenter.org/UploadedPDF/413286-reforming-state-gas-tax.pdf.
  366. US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. “Office of Highway Policy Information,” tables 4.2.1 and 8.2.1, www.fhwa.dot.gov/policyinformation/statistics/2014/; US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. “Ask the Rambler.” www.fhwa.dot.gov/infrastructure/gastax.cfm (gas taxes); BLS. CPI Inflation calculator.
  367. Kearney, Melissa S., et al. “Racing Ahead or Falling Behind: Six Economic Facts About Transportation Infrastructure in the United States?” The Hamilton Project, May 2015, sec. 5, www.hamiltonproject.org/assets/files/six_econ_facts_transportation_infrastructure_united_states_final.pdf.
  368. University of Massachusetts Amherst/WBZ. “Crosstabs: U Mass Amherst/WBZ Poll of Massachusetts Registered Voters.” Ballot Question 1, cbsboston.files.wordpress.com/2014/09/crosstabs_september29_final.pdf.
  369. Lehman, Chris. “Oregon to Test Switching to Mileage-Based Gas Tax.” NPR, 1 June 2015, www.npr.org/2015/06/01/411138483/oregon-to-test-switching-to-mileage-based-gas-tax.
  370. Public Law 114-41; US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. “Highway Trust Fund Ticker: Highway Account By Month,” www.transportation.gov/highway-trust-fund-ticker.
  371. Broder, John M. “Democrats Divided over Gas Tax.” New York Times, 29 Apr. 2008, www.nytimes.com/2008/04/29/us/politics/29campaign.html?partner=rssuserland&emc=rss&pagewanted=all&_r=0; Luhby, Tami. “U.S. Highway Fund Crushed by Cutback in Driving.” CNN Money, 5 Sept. 2008.
  372. US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. “Financial Federal-Aid Highways: The Highway Trust Fund.” www.fhwa.dot.gov/reports/fifahiwy/fifahi05.htm.
  373. Supra note 14, “2015 Urban Mobility Score Card.” Ex. 1.
  374. BLS. “American Time Use,” 2014, table A-1.
  375. See American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, 2013, generally; see also US Public Interest Research Group. Madsen, Travis, et al. “Road Work Ahead: Holding Government Accountable for Fixing America’s Crumbling Roads and Bridges,” Apr. 2010, p. 15 et seq.
  376. TRIP. “Bumpy Roads Ahead: America’s Roughest Rides and Strategies to Make Our Road Smoother,” July 2015, Appendix A.
  377. Tuss, Adam. “New Report: D.C. Area Really Does Have the Worst Traffic in the U.S.” NBC 4, 5 Feb. 2013, www.nbcwashington.com/news/local/New-Report-DC-Really-Does-Have-the-Worst-Traffic-in-the-US-189744731.html; USA Today, and Scott Broom, WUSA. “Report: DC Traffic Is the Worst in the U.S.” 26 Aug. 2015, www.wusa9.com/story/news/2015/08/26/report-dc-traffic-worst-us/32440837/.
  378. US Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. “Highway Bridges by State and Highway System.” 31 Dec 2015, www.fhwa.dot.gov/bridge/nbi/no10/defbr15.cfm#a, and see infra note 31.
  379. Ibid.; see also American Society of Civil Engineers, Infrastructure Report Card 2013, Bridges Subsection.
  380. Nixon, Ron. “$11 Billion Later, High-Speed Rail Is Inching Along.” New York Times, 6 Aug. 2014, www.nytimes.com/2014/08/07/us/delays-persist-for-us-high-speedrail.html?emc=edit_th_20140807&nl=todaysheadlines&nlid=45299538&_r=0; 49 USC §26105.2.A. (defining “high-speed rail”).
  381. Nussbaum, Paul. “Amtrak’s High-Speed Northeast Corridor Plan at $151 Billion.” Inquirer, 10 July 2012, posted on Philly.com, articles.philly.com/2012-07-10/news/32602302_1_amtrak-president-joseph-boardman-acela-express-northeast-corridor; Amtrak. “Amtrak Vision for the Northeast Corridor: 2012 Update Report,” 2012, p. 28.
  382. E.g., “World Speed Survey 2007: New Lines Boost Rail’s High Speed Performance.” Railway Gazette, 4 Sept. 2007, www.railwaygazette.com/news/single-view/view/world-speed-survey-new-lines-boost-rails-high-speed-performance.html; “Top Ten Fastest Trains in the World.” Railway-technology.com, 29 Aug. 2013, www.railway-technology.com/features/feature-top-ten-fastest-trains-in-the-world.
  383. American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, 2013, p. 67.
  384. Fandos, Nicholas. “Lengthy Shutdowns in Washington, D.C. Metro System Are Possible.” New York Times, 30 Mar. 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/03/31/us/lengthy-shutdowns-in-washington-dc-metro-system-are-possible.html.
  385. American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, 2013, p. 67.
  386. US Government Accountability Office. “Commercial Nuclear Waste: Effects of a Termination of the Yucca Mountain Repository Program and Lessons Learned.” GAO-11-1129, released on 10 May 2011, www.gao.gov/assets/320/317634.html; see also US Government Accountability Office. GAO Testimony, GAO-13-532T, 11 Apr. 2013, introduction and generally.
  387. American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, 2013, p. 15.
  388. US Army Corp of Engineers. “National Inventory of Dams.” June 2016; Association of State Dam Safety Officials. “2014 Statistics on State Dam Safety Regulation,” Aug. 2015; see also Poindexter, Gregory B. “Alabama Remains Only U.S. State Lacking a State Dam Safety Program.” HydroWorld.com, 23 Dec. 2015, www.hydroworld.com/articles/2015/12/alabama-remains-only-u-s-state-lacking-a-state-dam-safety-program.html.
  389. US Army Corp of Engineers. “National Inventory of Dams,” June 2016; Association of State Dam Safety Officials. “2014 Statistics on State Dam Safety Regulation,” Aug. 2015.
  390. Ibid.; author’s calculations.
  391. New York City, Department of Environmental Protection. “City Water Tunnel No. 3,” www.nyc.gov/html/dep/html/dep_projects/cp_city_water_tunnel3.shtml.
  392. Ibid.
  393. In 2013, for example, the DoD requested about $150 billion for compensation expenses, including benefits and health care for present and former personnel, out of a total budget of about $470 billion, or roughly 1/3rd. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “Costs of Military Pay and Benefits in the Defense Budget,” 14 Nov. 14, 2012. In a very substantial way, the military is and for some time has been, a jobs program.
  394. Constitution of the United States, article I, sec. 8.
  395. 45 USC §5501 and Public Law 101–427 (1990).
  396. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “Updated Budget Projections: 2016 to 2026,” 24 Mar. 2016, fig 4.
  397. White House, Office of Management and Budget. “Outlays by Function and Superfunction—National Defense.” Historical Tables, table 3.2, www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals. The sequester was based on legislation passed in 2011 and 2013 and was triggered in 2014 and 2015. If spending falls below legislated caps, there is no sequestration per se, although the budgets submitted to Congress are clearly drafted with the sequester in mind, and therefore the sequester has similar effects whether or not it is explicitly triggered.
  398. US Department of Defense. Quadrennial Defense Review 2014, p. viii.
  399. Ibid., p. 22.
  400. National Defense Panel. “Ensuring a Strong U.S. Defense for the Future: The National Defense Panel Review of the 2014 Quadrennial Defense Review.” Advance copy, 31 July 2014, p. 29.
  401. Ibid.
  402. Ibid., p. 30.
  403. Ibid.
  404. US Marine Corps. “Opening Statement to the Defense Subcommittee—House Appropriations Committee on Posture of the United States Marine Corps.” Presented by Joseph F. Dunford Jr., 26 Feb. 2015.
  405. Heritage Foundation. “2016 Index of U.S. Military Strength,” pp. 228, 234; O’Hanlon, Michael E. “The Future of the U.S. Army.” Brookings, 18 Sept. 2015 (noting that the present army is “fairly small by most relevant measures,” that the author “would oppose” future reductions—which were contemplated, and that certain of parts of the QDR were “mistaken”).
  406. “Houston Police Department Operational Staffing Model.” Police Executive Research Forum, May 2014, p. 150, www.houstontx.gov/police/department_reports/operational_staffing/Houston_Police_Department_Operational_Staffing_Model_May_2014.pdf; Estonian Defense Forces, www.mil.ee/en/defence-forces. Bendavid, Naftali. “Just Five of 28 NATO Members Meet Defense Spending Goal, Report Says.” 22 June 2015; North Atlantic Treaty Organization. “Defense Expenditures of NATO Countries (2008–2015),” 28 Jan. 2016, p. 2; North Atlantic Treaty Organization. “Readiness Action Plan.” 23 June 2016 (the “Wales Summit 2014”).
  407. White House, Office of Management and Budget. Historical Debt Tables, table 14.5, www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Historicals.
  408. Petroski, Henry. The Road Taken: The History and Future of America’s Infrastructure. Bloomsbury, 16 Feb. 2016, p. 85; BLS. CPI Inflation calculator; Van Derbeken, Jaxon. “Bay Bridge Fix in Place, $25 Million Later.” SF Gate, 19 Dec. 2013, www.sfgate.com/default/article/Bay-Bridge-fix-in-place-25-million-later-5076643.php.
  409. Fitzsimmons, Emma G. “$2.4 Billion Subway Stop Was Leaking Before It Opened.” New York Times, 29 Mar. 2016, mobile.nytimes.com/2016/03/30/nyregion/documents-reveal-early-concerns-about-leaks-at-hudson-yards-subway-station.html.
    Chapter 11: Boomer Finance: The Vicious Cycle of Risk and Deceit
  410. DSM-V, p. 660.
  411. Courtauld, George. England’s Best Loved Poems: The Enchantment of England. Random House eBooks, sec. 5.
  412. Hitchens, Christopher. And Yet… Essays, e-books ed., p. 468 (first printed in Slate, “The Case Against Hillary.” 14 Jan. 2008); see also Purdum, Todd. “Hillary Clinton Meets Man Who Gave Her 2 L’s.” New York Times, 3 Apr. 1995 (repeating improbable story by Clinton); see also “Edmund Hillary.” Biography.com.
  413. E.g., Securities Act of 1933; Securities Exchange Act of 1934; Investment Company Act of 1940; Investment Advisers Act of 1940; Banking Act of 1933 (Glass-Steagall; established FDIC); Commodity Exchange Act of 1936; Commodity Futures Trading Commission Act of 1974.
  414. Brandeis, Louis D. Other People’s Money—And How the Bankers Use It. Martino ed., 2009, p. 92.
  415. Leeds, Jeff. “Andersen Auditor Details Shredding of Enron Papers.” Los Angeles Times, 14 May 2002, articles.latimes.com/2002/may/14/business/fi-andersen14; Associated Press. “In Depositions, Arthur Andersen Staffers Detail ‘Shred Room.’” Fox News, 15 Mar. 2002, www.foxnews.com/story/2002/03/15/in-depositions-arthur-andersen-staffers-detail-shred-room.html.
  416. US Department of the Treasury, Bureau of the Fiscal Service. “Financial Report of the United States Government—2015,” 25 Feb. 2016, pp. 18, 82 et seq.
  417. Ibid., pp. 138–165. Pagination is based on the overall document’s pagination appearing at the top left; subparts have their own pagination.
  418. Ibid., “Statement of the Comptroller General,” pp. 11, 37–38.
  419. Ibid., p. 40.
  420. No one really knows how large OBS liabilities are. Sometimes people cite some truly extraordinary figures—no less than the world’s economic product and often vastly more—but these are often based on face/notional values, rather than probable exposure or cash paid, and many of these liabilities net (Bank A may lose $1 million on an OBS item, while Bank B gains $1 million and this may say nothing about the system as a whole). Nevertheless, it’s clear that the total outstanding is quite large; e.g., US Federal Reserve, “Financial Accounts of the United States,” table L.111 (Q2 2016) (noting about $40 trillion in “other” derivatives, $14 trillion in interest derivatives, and assorted trillions, for just “Depository Institutions: Off-Balance Sheet Items”). The net, real exposure is probably an order of magnitude smaller—which is still a lot.
  421. Rogin, Joshn. “Fiorina’s HP Earned Millions from Sales in Iran.” Bloomberg, 14 Sept. 2015, www.bloombergview.com/articles/2015-09-14/under-fiorina-hp-earned-millions-from-sales-in-iran.
  422. Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act, sec. 101.
  423. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. “History of the Eighties—Lessons for the Future,” vol. 1, 1997, p. 240.
  424. Brooker, Katrina. “Citi’s Creator, Alone with His Regrets.” New York Times, 2 Jan 2010, www.nytimes.com/2010/01/03/business/economy/03weill.html?pagewanted=1&_r=0.
  425. Labaton, Stephen. “Agency’s ’04 Rule Let Banks Pile Up New Debt.” New York Times, 2 Oct. 2008, www.nytimes.com/2008/10/03/business/03sec.html.
  426. For an interesting narrative history, see “Money, Power and Wall Street.” PBS. Frontline, www.pbs.org/wgbh/frontline/film/money-power-wall-street/transcript/.
  427. Labaton.
  428. Nakamoto, Michiyo, and David Wighton. “Citigroup Chief Stays Bullish on Buy-outs.” Financial Times, 9 July 2007.
  429. US Securities and Exchange Commission. “SEC Halts Short Selling of Financial Stocks to Protect Investors and Markets,” 19 Sept. 2008, www.sec.gov/news/press/2008/2008-211.htm.
  430. Ibid.
  431. United States Census. Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2012. Internet preamble, www.census.gov/library/publications/2011/compendia/statab/131ed.html; Samuelson, Robert J. “Don’t Kill America’s Databook.” Washington Post, 21 Aug. 2011.
  432. Labaton.
  433. Financial Accounting Standards Board. Statement No. 157, generally p. 15 (regarding “Level 3 inputs”); Financial Accounting Standards Board of the Financial Accounting Foundation. “Fair Value Measurement (Topic 820): Amendments to Achieve Common Fair Value Measurement and Disclosure Requirements in U.S. GAAP and IFRSs.” Financial Accounting Series. Accounting Standards Update, No. 2011-04, May 2011; US Securities and Exchange Commission. “SEC Office of the Chief Accountant and FASB Staff Clarifications on Fair Value Accounting.” Release 2008-234, 30 Sept. 2008; US Securities and Exchange Commission. “Investment Company Act of 1940—Section 2(a) (41) and Rules 2a-4 and 22c-1: Investment Company Institute Designated NRSROs.” 19 Aug. 2010.
  434. The Federal Reserve Act (1977 amendments); Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. “The Federal Reserve’s Dual Mandate.” www.chicagofed.org/publications/speeches/our-dual-mandate.
  435. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. “Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet.” www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_recenttrends.htm, Aug. 2007–Dec. 2015.
  436. Sanders, Bernie. “Transcript: Bernie Sanders Meets with the Daily News Editorial Board.” New York Daily News, 4 Apr. 2016, www.nydailynews.com/opinion/transcript-bernie-sanders-meets-news-editorial-board-article-1.2588306.
  437. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. Statistical table 8. “Table 8. Initial margin requirements Under Regulations T, U, and X” (as percentage of market value).
  438. New York Stock Exchange, “FRB Initial margin requirements—percent of total value required to purchase stock,” http://www.nyxdata.com/nysedata/asp/factbook/viewer_edition.asp?mode=table&key=52&category=8.
  439. Fortune, Peter. “Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles.” New England Economic Review, Sept.–Oct. 2000, pp. 43–44, www.bostonfed.org/economic/neer/neer2000/neer500b.pdf. Fortune began his article by positioning it at something of a direct response to Shiller’s lament about margin requirements. To be fair, Fortune made some technical distinctions between initial, maintenance, and other margins, but missed the main point, as the crash showed.
  440. Lahart, Justin. “S&P 500 Earnings: Far Worse Than Advertised.” Wall Street Journal, 24 Feb. 2016.
  441. Case-Schiller Cyclically Adjusted P/E Ratio, available via yCharts (series: I:SP500CAP). This cyclically adjusted ratio is not without its controversies, but is the best data set offering perspective over the long, long term. The raw S&P 500 P/E ratio was 11.7 in Q4 1988, 18.1 in Q4 1995, 30.5 in Q4 1999, and was around 23–25 in the first half of 2016. The story, in other words, is the same. The case could be made that things are somewhat better or somewhat worse—somewhat better because models digest interest rates, and interest rates are low, “justifying” higher valuations; somewhat worse, because of survivorship bias, the rise of ultra-high P/E ratios in private equity (if there’s any “E” at all), etc. My view is that things are probably somewhat worse.
  442. Holland, A. Steven. “Real Interest Rates: What Accounts for Their Rise?” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Dec. 1984, pp. 1–3 (online pagination), research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/84/12/Rates_Dec1984.pdf. Note that Holland was measuring Treasury rates, not consumer rates, but the one drove the other; e.g., FRED MORTG vs. CPI (suggesting that real thirty-year mortgage rates verged toward 0 percent at times).
  443. Ibid. The FRED database provides a number of consumer credit interest rates for everything from mortgages to credit cards, which can be usefully compared and show the same pattern.
    Chapter 12: The Brief Triumph of Long Retirement
  444. Banerjee, Sudipto. “Change in Household Spending after Retirement: Results from a Longitudinal Sample.” Employee Benefit Research Institute (hereinafter “EBRI”). No. 420, Nov. 2015, www.ebri.org/pdf/briefspdf/EBRI_IB_420.Nov15.HH-Exp.pdf. I’ve adjusted to include changes in payments to mortgage spending—if mortgages are included, the average numbers rise further, while the median remains unaffected, so I have presented the lowest bound for the median, and the lowest bound for the average to be conservative; see also Butrica, Barbara, et al., “Understanding Expenditure Patterns in Retirement,” Urban Institute, 18 Jan. 2005, www.urban.org/sites/default/files/alfresco/publication_pdfs/411130-Understanding-Expenditure-Patterns-in-Retirement.pdf. Note that different studies use different numbers, cohorts, processes, etc., but all come to the same general conclusion—retirement spending is ~80 percent of preretirement spending, at least in the early years. Spending in later years may decline as fewer trips are taken, though medical expenses grow.
  445. FRED, PSAVERT; author’s calculations. For the estimate of savings necessary on a “cash basis,” I’ve assumed all savings are invested in very low-risk securities with a 2 percent real yield, a constant income and constant savings rate, that gains on retirement savings are continuous and not taxed until retirement, and that no additional sources of income are available. Every variable can be easily debated, but with the significant exception of the assumed rate of return, that method tends to be unduly generous to the savings rate. The point is that the savings rate can and should have been much higher, even if returns were closer to 5–6% in real terms.
  446. Library of Congress, Congressional Research Service. Topoleski, John J. “U.S. Household Savings for Retirement in 2010,” 23 July 2013, fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/R43057.pdf; Morrissey, Monique. “The State of American Retirement: How 401(k)s Have Failed Most American Workers,” Mar. 2016, table 3 et seq., Economic Policy Institute, www.epi.org/publication/retirement-in-america/.
  447. FRED, PSAVERT.
  448. Ibid.
  449. OECD. “Household Savings: Total % of Household Disposable Income, 2000–2015,” data.oecd.org/hha/household-savings.htm#indicator-chart. It’s important to emphasize the methodological differences between how the United States calculates savings and how the rest of the OECD does (since the rest of the OECD has substantial pension plans); and changes in plan values are important and included. To the extent changes in the US plans are included, as we will see, they would most likely further reduce American rates, quite substantially.
  450. Helman, Ruth, et al. “The 2015 Retirement Confidence Survey.” EBRI. No. 413, Apr. 2015, pp. 13, 16–23, www.ebri.org/pdf/briefspdf/EBRI_IB_413_Apr15_RCS-2015.pdf.
  451. Roosevelt, Franklin D. “FDR’s Statements on Social Security.” Presidential Statements. Message to Congress Reviewing the Broad Objectives and Accomplishments of the Administration, 8 June 1934. Social Security Administration, www.ssa.gov/history/fdrstmts.html.
  452. US Department of Housing and Urban Development. “FHA Reverse Mortgages (HECMs) for Seniors.” portal.hud.gov/hudportal/HUD?src=/program_offices/housing/sfh/hecm/hecmabou.
  453. Butrica, Barbara A. “The Disappearing Defined Benefit Pension and Its Potential Impact on the Retirement Incomes of Baby Boomers.” Social Security Bulletin, vol. 69, no. 3, 2009, p. 1, www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/ssb/v69n3/v69n3p1.pdf.
  454. Norris, Floyd. “Private Pension Plans, Even at Big Companies, May Be Underfunded.” New York Times, 20 July 2012, nytimes.com/2012/07/21/business/pension-plans-increasingly-underfunded-at-largest-companies.html?_r=0 (citing $355 billion as of 2012 for just the S&P 500 companies).
  455. Novy-Marx, Robert, and Joshua Ruah. “The Intergenerational Transfer of Public Pension Promises.” National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper No. 14343, Sept. 2008; Novy-Marx, Robert, and Joshua D. Ruah, “The Revenue Demands of Public Employee Pension Promises.” National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper No. 18489, Oct. 2012, p. 31.
  456. Walsh, Mary Williams. “A Sour Surprise for Pensions: Two Sets of Books.” New York Times, 17 Sept. 2016, http://www.nytimes.com/2016/09/18/business/dealbook/a-sour-surprise-for-public-pensions-two-sets-of-books.html?_r=0.
  457. Martin, Timothy W. “Treasury Department Rejects Teamsters’ Central States Proposal to Cut Retiree Benefits.” Wall Street Journal, 6 May 2016, www.wsj.com/articles/treasury-department-rejects-teamsters-central-states-proposal-to-cut-retiree-benefits-1462558028.
  458. Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation. “2015 Annual Report: Preserving and Protecting Pensions.” 2015, pp. 23–28, www.pbgc.gov/Documents/2015-annual-report.pdf.
  459. Ibid., pp. 24, 28, 36.
  460. Office of Inspector General. Semiannual Report to Congress, Apr. 2015, pp. 6, 9–10, available at Office of Inspector General, Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation Audit Report. Prior and subsequent reports found essentially the same things; e.g., Office of Inspector General, Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation Audit Report, Nov. 2015.
  461. Roosevelt, Franklin. “Message to Congress Reviewing the Broad Objectives and Accomplishments of the Administration.” 8 June 1934.
  462. CDC. Life Tables, table A, 2011, www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr64/nvsr64_11.pdf; CDC. Life Tables, table 6-A, 1982, www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/lifetables/life82_2acc.pdf.
  463. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College (summarizing and interpreting Census information). “Frequently Requested Data.” Mar. 2013. Retirement Period of Males, 1962–2050, crr.bc.edu/wp-content/uploads/1012/01/figure-101.pdf, and Average Retirement Age for Men, 1962–2012, crr.bc.edu/wp-content/uploads/1012/01/Avg_ret_age_men1.pdf. The age of average retirement reached a low in the 1990s and has since risen, but so has longevity, with the result that the total length of nonworking years has increased.
  464. Author’s calculations; see also Helman, Ruth, et al. “The 2016 Retirement Confidence Survey: Worker Confidence Stable, Retiree Confidence Continues to increase.” EBRI. No. 422, Mar. 2016, p. 26 (noting that 48 percent think they need at least $500,000 and up to over $1.5 million to retire).
  465. Helman, “The 2016 Retirement Confidence Survey,” p. 5. Retirees become somewhat more confident, but people presently retired also have the greatest likelihood of collecting pension benefits and entitlements, which are evaporating for present workers.
  466. FRED. CPIMEDSL vs. CPIAUSCL (BLS).
  467. Medicare Trustees Report 2015, p. 41 and Appendix J (Statement of Actuarial Opinion), at 258.
  468. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, National Association of State Retirement Administrators. “Issue Brief: Public Pension Plan Investment Return Assumptions.” Feb. 2016, p. 3; see also Public Plans Data. “National Data,” publicplansdata.org/quick-facts/national/.
  469. Ibid.; see also Martin, Timothy. “Public Pensions Roll Back Return Targets.” Wall Street Journal, 4 Sept. 2015, www.wsj.com/articles/taxpayers-more-pension-burdens-headed-your-way-1441388090#:U_KmuhxfW4eYXA.
  470. Social Security Administration. “Social Security History, Supreme Court Case: Fleming vs. Nestor.” Social Security Online, www.ssa.gov/history/nestor.html.
  471. 363 US 603 (1960).
  472. Library of Congress, Congressional Research Service. Meyerson, Noah P. “Social Security: What Would Happen If the Trust Funds Ran Out?” 28 Aug. 2014, p. 6, www.fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/RL33514.pdf. Meyerson is a little cursory in his description, but he seems to take the idea of legal entitlement a little more seriously than, say, the Supreme Court does.
  473. 42 USC 1303.
  474. Mettler, Suzanne, and Julianna Koch. “Who Says They Have Ever Used a Government Social Program? The Role of Policy Visibility.” Cornell University, Department of Government. 28 Feb. 2012, p. 36, government.arts.cornell.edu/assets/faculty/docs/mettler/PerceptionGovt-KochMettler-022812.pdf.
  475. Ventura, Elbert. “The Tea Party Paradox.” Columbia Journalism Review, Jan.–Feb. 2012; see generally Williamson, Vanessa, et al. “The Tea Party and the Remaking of Republican Conservatism.” Perspective on Politics, vol. 9, no. 1, Mar. 2011, p. 33.
  476. Steuerle, C. Eugene, and Caleb Quakenbush. “Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes.” Urban Institute. Sept. 2015, table 15. Measurements in 2015 dollars, both earning “average” wages, presented as present values. See their discussion for important assumptions about payouts, earnings histories, and discount rates (which seem reasonable).
  477. E.g., The Board of Trustees, Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Fund. The 2015 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds, 2015 (hereinafter “2015 SSA Annual Report”), pp. 6, 25, et seq., https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2015/tr2015.pdf; Medicare Trustees Report 2015.
  478. Clingman, Michael, et al. “Internal Real Rates of Return under the OASDI Program for Hypothetical Workers.” Actuarial Note, no. 2015.5, Mar. 2016, table 1 et seq. (noting that internal rates of return fall toward 2.5 percent annually for average groups and under 1 percent for the youngest and richest, should cuts or benefits be enacted post-2033).
  479. Kaiser Foundation. “Overview of Medicare Spending.” kff.org/medicare/fact-sheet/medicare-spending-and-financing-fact-sheet/; see also Medicare Trustees Report 2015, pp. 23, 34, 38–40.
  480. Levin, Josh. “The Welfare Queen.” Slate, 19 Dec. 2013, www.slate.com/articles/news_and_politics/history/2013/12/linda_taylor_welfare_queen_ronald_reagan_made_her_a_notorious_american_villain.html.
  481. Medicare. “Medicare’s Wheelchair & Scooter Benefit.” Revised Apr. 2014, www.medicare.gov/Pubs/pdf/11046.pdf.
  482. Koltikoff, Laurence J., et al. Get What’s Yours: The Secrets to Maxing Out Your Social Security. Simon & Schuster, 17 Feb. 2015, p. 5.
  483. Ibid.
  484. Ibid., p. 113.
  485. Ibid., back cover.
  486. 2015 SSA Annual Report, table IV.B3, 2015, p. 61. https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2015/tr2015.pdf.
  487. Public Law 113-270, (2014; “No Social Security for Nazis Act”).
  488. 2015 SSA Annual Report, table IV.B.3. Note that projections are for SSA’s “intermediate” scenario and include the much smaller population of disabled persons as beneficiaries, per SSA methodology.
  489. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “A Detailed Description of CBO’s Cost Estimate for the Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit.” July 2014, p. viii, www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/108th-congress-2003-2004/reports/07-21-medicare.pdf. Medicare Trustees Report 2015, table IV.B10. There would have been immaterial reductions due to technical changes of certain provisions, with the lowest net cost to federal spending being $395 billion.
  490. Ramey, Corinne, “Insurers Probed on Hepatitis C Drug Coverage.” Wall Street Journal, 2 Mar. 2016, www.wsj.com/articles/insurers-probed-on-hepatitis-c-drug-coverage-1456965087.
  491. New York State Department of Health. “State Health Department Urges Hepatitis C Testing,” May 15, 2014, https://www.health.ny.gov/press/releases/2014/2014-05-14_may_hepatitis_awareness_month.htm; Ramey.
  492. Medicare Trustees Report 2015, p. 198. See also note 51.
  493. Certain groups of non-seniors, like the permanently disabled, may qualify for Medicare benefits. Most non-seniors do not.
  494. National Institute for Health Care Management. “The Concentration of Health Care Spending.” July 2012.
  495. Osborn, Robin, et al. “International Survey of Older Adults Finds Shortcomings in Access, Coordination and Patient-Centered Care.” Health Affairs, vol. 33, no. 12, 2014, pp. 2247–2255; United Health Foundation. America’s Health Rankings, 2016, p. 21; “America’s Health Rankings: Senior Report,” 2016, United Health Foundation. https://assets.americashealthrankings/org/app/uploads/final-report-seniors-edition-1.pdf.
  496. Social Security Administration. “Social Security History, ch. 4: The Fourth Round: 1957 to 1965,” www.ssa.gov/history/corningchap4.html.
  497. Medicare Trustees Report 2015, p. 198 (intermediate assumptions); US Census. “Person Income in 2015.” Current Population Survey, 26 Aug. 2016; Kirby G. Posey. “Household Income: 2015.” US Census, 16 Sept. 2016; author’s calculations. There are certain differences in how Medicare accounts for costs, but these are immaterial. The larger question is whether, as Medicare itself suspects, costs will be much higher.
  498. Medicare Trustees Report 2015, p. 198.
  499. Ibid., pp. 69–71. Under “infinite horizon” scenarios, the number is higher, but these estimates are uncertain.
  500. Ibid., p. 70.
  501. Ibid., Appendix V.C.
  502. Ibid., p. 194.
  503. US Department of Health and Human Services, Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, Office of the Actuary. “Projected Medicare Expenditures Under Current Law, the Projected Baseline, and an Illustrative Alternative Scenario.” 28 Aug. 2014, pp. 1, 14–16, www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/ReportsTrustFunds/Downloads/2014TRAlternativeScenario.pdf.
  504. Munnell, Alicia H., et al. “Are Retirees Falling Short? Reconciling the Conflicting Evidence,” pp. 5, 22. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, crr.bc.edu/working-papers/are-retirees-falling-short-reconciling-the-conflicting-evidence/. The paper attempt to reconcile more and less optimistic scenarios, but trends toward the less optimistic.
    Chapter 13: Preparing for the Future
  505. DSM-V, pp. 659–660.
  506. Winthrop, John. “A Model of Christian Charity” (1630). Collections of the Massachusetts Historical Society. 3rd series, 7:31–48, 1838, history.hanover.edu/texts/winthmod.html.
  507. US Department of the Interior, National Parks Service. “Theodore Roosevelt and Conservation.” www.nps.gov/thro/learn/historyculture/theodore-roosevelt-and-conservation.htm; US Department of Agriculture. “Major Uses of Land in the United States.” 2002, p. 1, www.ers.usda.gov/media/250091/eib14_1_.pdf.
  508. Public Law 88-206; amended by Public Laws 90-148, 91-604, 95-95, and 101-549; see also US Environmental Protection Agency. “Clean Air Act Overview.” www.epa.gov/clean-air-act-overview/clean-air-act-text.
  509. Ibid.
  510. Chevron USA v. NRDC, 467 US 837 (1984); Auer v. Robbins, 519 US 452 (1997). Three justices abstained in Chevron for various reasons, but the remainder were unanimous; Auer was also unanimous. Justice Scalia delivered the Auer opinion, and then subsequently seemed to try to walk it back; he died, but the war against Chevron/Auer deference seems to be taking on new life.
  511. Michigan v. Environmental Protection Agency (2015), slip opinion available at www.supremecourt.gov/opinions/14pdf/14-46_10n2.pdf. Whether the Supreme Court ever really took its own rulings seriously, lower courts were certainly bound by them. For a general discussion, see Saxman, Seth P. “The State of Chevron: 15 Years After Mead.” Administrative Law Review Accord, vol. 68, 24 Mar. 2016, and also the writings of Bill Eskridge.
  512. Turque, Bill. “Inventing Al Gore: A Biography.” Houghton Mifflin, 2000, p. 133.
  513. Ibid., pp. 105–106.
  514. Ibid.; Morrison, Micah. “Al Gore, Environmentalist and Zinc Miner.” Wall Street Journal, Commentary, 29 June 2000, www.wsj.com/articles/SB96224176442047890; Theobald, Bill. “Environmentalist Gore Allowed Zinc Mine.” USA Today, 18 Mar. 2007, usatoday30.usatoday.com/news/nation/2007-03-18-goremine_N.htm; Hennenberger, Melinda. “Al Gore’s Petrodollars Once Again Make Him a Chip off the Old Block.” Washington Post, 8 Jan. 2013, www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/she-the-people/wp/2013/01/08/al-gores-petrodollars-once-again-make-him-a-chip-off-the-old-block/; Douglas, Frantz. “The 2000 Campaign: The Vice President; Gore Family’s Ties to Oil Company Magnate Reap Big Rewards, and a Few Problems.” New York Times, 19 Mar. 2000; Center for Public Integrity. “How the Gores, Father and Son, Helped Their Patron Occidental Petroleum,” 11 Jan. 2000, www.publicintegrity.org/2000/01/11/3315/how-gores-father-and-son-helped-their-patron-occidental-petroleum.
  515. Nussbaum, Bruce. “Al Gore’s Carbon Footprint Is Big.” Bloomberg, 27 Feb. 2007, www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2007-02-26/al-gores-carbon-footprint-is-big-dot.
  516. “Worldwide Effort Is Proposed to Study Climate and Its Impact.” Special Contribution. New York Times, 13 Feb. 1979, C3; see also World Meteorological Organization. “World Climate Programme (WCP).” www.wmo.int/pages/prog/wcp/wcp.html; Bierly, Eugene W. “The World Climate Program: Collaboration and Communication on a Global Scale.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, vol. 495, Jan. 1988, pp. 113–114.
  517. Infra note 14–15; and Betts, Richard A., et al. “When Could Global Warming Reach 4°C?” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society, vol. 369, no. 1934, 2011, pp. 67–84.
  518. IPCC. Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2013, www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar5/wg1/WG1AR5_Chapter01_FINAL.pdf (hereinafter “IPCC”), chapter 1 generally, figure 1.9, chapter 13 (separate contribution), and author’s calculations. For more recent and dire predictions, see DeConto, Robert M., and David Pollard. “Contribution of Antarctica to Past and Future Sea-Level Rise.” Nature. vol. 531, 31 Mar. 2016, p. 591; Hansen, James, et al. “Ice Melt, Sea Level Rise and Superstorms: Evidence From Paleoclimate Data, Climate Modeling, and Modern Observations that 2°C Global Warming Could Be Dangerous.” Atmospheric Chemistry and Physics, vol. 16, no. 6, 22 Mar. 2016.
  519. E.g., Fox, Douglas. “Scientists Are Watching In Horror as Ice Collapses.” National Geographic, 12 Apr. 2016.
  520. Pew Research Center. “Americans, Politics, and Science Issues.” p. 38, 42, www.pewinternet.org/files/2015/07/2015-07-01_science-and-politics_FINAL.pdf. (A popup appears saying this file is an embargoed draft, but it’s posted in several places on Pew, marked as final, and cited in Pew’s press releases; it appears final). The effects of age appear somewhat more important even than the effects of education, but more research is required to detangle the variables.
  521. Doran, Peter T., Maggie Kendall Zimmerman. “Examining the Scientific Consensus on Climate Change.” Eos, Transactions American Geophysical Union. AGU Publications, vol. 90, no. 3, pp. 22–33; Cook, John, et al. “Quantifying the Consensus on Anthropogenic Global Warming in the Scientific Literature.” IOPscience, Environmental Research Letters. 15 May 2013 (suggesting >97 percent consensus among those expressing an opinion).
  522. Supra note 16, p. 52 et seq.
  523. Ibid., p. 37.
  524. Stokes, Bruce, et al. “Global Concern About Climate Change, Broad Support for Limiting Emissions.” Pew Research Center, 5 Nov. 2015, p. 20. Younger people are substantially more likely to believe climate change will affect them personally, but are still unrealistic.
  525. US Environmental Protection Agency. “US Greenhouse Gas Emissions by Gas Inventory Report: 1990–2014.” www3.epa.gov/climatechange/ghgemissions/usinventoryreport.html; and US Environmental Protection Agency. “Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Sinks: 1990–2014.” 15 Apr. 2016, at ES-1. On a per capita basis, there has been some improvement, but per capita is not the most relevant metric for this issue.
  526. Ibid., sec. 8 (noting US calculation exclusion of “Other”); IPCC, sec. 5.4; OECD. “Carbon Dioxide Emissions Embodied in International Trade.” Sept. 2015, www.oecd.org/industry/ind/carbondioxideemissionsembodiedininternationaltrade.htm and associated spreadsheets and author’s calculations. The Obama administration’s plan for cuts is a reduction by 2025 of 26 to 28 percent below 2005 levels, or about 2.5 percent annually as a crude average. “U.S. Cover Note, INDC and Accompanying Information.” It remains to be seen how the late 2016 acceptance by Obama of the Paris Accords changes this target. United States of America, “Submission,” 31 Mar. 2015, www4.unfccc.int/Submissions/INDC/Published%20Documents/United%20States%20of%20America/1/U.S.%20Cover%20Note%20INDC%20and%20Accompanying%20Information.pdf.
  527. US Energy Information Administration. “Total Petroleum and Other Liquids Production, 2014,” www.eia.gov/beta/international/rankings/#?prodact=53-1&cy=2014 and author’s calculations. See also EIA at www.eia.gov/beta/international.
  528. Ibid.
  529. Cook, Lynn, and Erin Ailworth. “First Tanker of U.S. Crude Oil for Export Sails From Texas.” Wall Street Journal, 31 Dec. 2015.
  530. US Dept. of Transportation. “Summary of Fuel Economy Performance.” 2013, pp. 3–4.
  531. Ibid.
  532. Author’s calculations. The delta in range estimates is a product of differences between linear vs. compound growth.
  533. IPCC. Annex II, table A.II, pp.18–19 et seq.
  534. US Department of Defense. “National Security Implications of Climate-Related Risks and a Changing Climate,” 23 July 2015, pp. 1, 14.
  535. Vidal, John, and David Adam. “China Overtakes US as World’s Biggest CO2 Emitter.” Guardian, 19 June 2007.
  536. Cushman Jr., John H. “U.S. Signs a Pact to Reduce Gases Tied to Warming.” New York Times, 13 Nov. 1998; 105th Congress, 1st Session, S. Res. 98 and Record Vote No. 205 (1997).
  537. Ibid. (Congressional vote).
  538. House Permanent Select Committee on Intelligence, House Select Committee on Energy Independence and Global Warming. “National Intelligence Assessment on the National Security Implications of Global Climate Change to 2030. Statement for the Record of Dr. Thomas Fingar,” 25 June 2008, fas.org/irp/congress/2008_hr/062508fingar.pdf.
  539. 102nd Congress, Senate Consideration of Treaty Document 102-38, 1992, www.congress.gov/treaty-document/102nd-congress/38 (aka the “Rio Treaty”).
  540. US Energy Information Administration. “Nuclear Reactor Operational Status Tables,” 2011.
  541. International Atomic Energy Agency. Power Reactor Information System, France, 2015.
  542. Sullivan, Peter. “Panel Members Clash over Fetal Tissue Subpoenas.” Hill, 2 Mar. 2016, thehill.com/policy/healthcare/271474-panel-members-clash-over-fetal-tissue-subpoenas.
  543. Phillips, Erica. “Massive Robots Keep Docks Shipshape.” Wall Street Journal, 27 Mar. 2016, www.wsj.com/articles/massive-robots-keep-docks-shipshape-1459104327.
    Chapter 14: Detention, After-School and Otherwise
  544. Attributed. Certainly, it’s consistent with Hugo’s general sentiments.
  545. Bureau of Justice Statistics. “Annual Probation Survey, Annual Parole Survey, Annual Survey of Jails, Census of Jail Inmates, and National Prisoner Statistics Program, 1980–2014,” appendix 1 and data file; US Census. “Table 1. Annual Estimates of the Resident Population for the United States, Regions, States, and Puerto Rico: April 1, 2010 to July 1, 2014.” NST-EST2014-01.
  546. Wirtz, Willard, et al. “On Further Examination: Report of the Advisory Panel on the Scholastic Aptitude Test Score Decline,” College Entrance Examination Board, 1977, table 2, research.collegeboard.org/sites/default/files/publications/2012/7/misc1977-1-report-sat-score-decline.pdf. See also US Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics, Digest of Education Statistics, 2014 (NCES 2016-006), chapter 2 and prior editions (hereinafter “NCES Digest” with relevant data specified).
  547. Wirtz, pp. 45–46.
  548. Ibid., sec. “Pervasive Change.”
  549. Ibid., sec. “Through Other Looking Glasses.”
  550. Ibid.
  551. Ibid., sec. “As It Was in the Beginning.”
  552. Ibid., sec. 8 and Part IV.
  553. Wirtz, table 2; “Scholastic Aptitude Test score averages for college-bound high school seniors, by sex: 1966–67 to 1993–94.” National Center for Education Statistics, 1995, nces.ed.gov/programs/digest/d95/dtab124.asp. The College Board has subsequently recentered and rescored the SAT, but during the period covered the scale remained the same.
  554. Reagan, Ronald. “State of the Union.” 25 Jan. 1984; National Commission on Excellence in Education. David Pierpont Gardner. “A Nation at Risk” and “Letter of Transmittal.” Apr. 1983.
  555. Gardner, “A Nation at Risk” and “Letter of Transmittal”; National Commission on Excellence in Education. Apr. 1983, sec. “Findings Regarding Expectations.”
  556. Ibid.
  557. Ibid.; Wirtz, p. 29.
  558. Seelye, Katharine Q. “Relentless Moral Crusader Is Relentless Gambler, Too.” New York Times, 3 May 2003, www.nytimes.com/2003/05/03/national/03GAMB.html. Bennett admitted to gambling, but said he also won; nevertheless, given how casinos make money, even if he’d just wagered $8 million he almost certainly lost a lot.
  559. Ravitch, Diane. “The Death and Life of the Great American School System: How Testing and Choice Are Undermining Education.” Basic Books, 2010, pp. 132–144 (citing multiple studies of all ideologies from public and private institutions).
  560. Ibid., pp. 266–267 (summarizing—correctly—the results of Matthew G. Springer, et al. “Teacher Pay for Performance.” National Center on Performance Incentives. Led by Vanderbilt Peabody College, 2010, pp. 43–49).
  561. US Department of Education. National Assessment of Education Progress. Table 221.30 (assessing 1984 to 2012; homework for the oldest students remained highly stable; some younger students are receiving somewhat less).
  562. Bromberg, Marni, and Christina Theokas. “Meandering Toward Graduation: Transcript Outcomes of High School Graduates.” Education Trust, Apr. 2016, p. 1.
  563. Ibid., pp. 4, 7.
  564. UC Berkeley, Office of Undergraduate Admissions. “Student Profile” for 2015 freshmen, admissions.berkeley.edu/studentprofile; U.S. News and World Report. “National Universities Rankings.” 2016 College Rankings, colleges.usnews.rankingsandreviews.com/best-colleges/rankings/national-universities/page+2.
  565. American Society of Civil Engineers. Infrastructure Report Card, 2013, pp. 7–8, 59, 67.
  566. Ibid., p. 7.
  567. OECD. “Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) Results from PISA 2012,” p. 1 et seq., www.oecd.org/unitedstates/PISA-2012-results-US.pdf.
  568. Duncan, Arne. “The Vison of Education Reform in the United States.” Speech to UNESCO, 4 Nov. 2010, unesco.usmission.gov/duncan-remarks.html.
  569. US Department of Education, Office of Inspector General. “The Office of Innovation and Improvement’s Oversight and Monitoring of the Charter Schools Program’s Planning and Implementation Grants.” p. 9, www2.ed.gov/about/offices/list/oig/auditreports/fy2012/a02l0002.pdf.
  570. NCES Digest. Table 208, Pupil/Teacher Ratio, 1955–2024.
  571. Ibid.
  572. National Assessment of Educational Progress. “Trends in Academic Progress: Reading 1971–2012, Mathematics 1973–2012.” The Nation’s Report Card, pp. 7 and 29.
  573. Ibid., p. 16.
  574. Ravitch, p. 31.
  575. Desilver, Drew. “U.S. Students Improving—Slowly—in Math and Science, but Still Lagging Internationally.” Pew Research Center, 2 Feb. 2015, www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2015/02/02/u-s-students-improving-slowly-in-math-and-science-but-still-lagging-internationally; National Center for Education Statistics. “Public High School Graduation Rates,” nces.ed.gov/programs/coe/indicator_coi.asp.
  576. E.g., Public Law 107-110 generally and at §§1117.a.5.i, 1119.a.3, 1501.a.2.A (2002).
  577. Hirschfeld Davis, Julie. “President Obama Signs into Law a Rewrite of No Child Left Behind.” New York Times, 10 Dec. 2015, nytimes.com/2015/12/11/us/politics/president-obama-signs-into-law-a-rewrite-of-no-child-left-behind.html?_r=0; PL 114-95.
  578. Almasy, Steve. “Atlanta Schools Cheating Scandal: 11 of 12 Defendants Convicted.” CNN, 14 Apr. 2015; Chandler, Michael Alison. “Six D.C. Schools Had ‘Critical’ Testing Violations, 11 Others Had Irregularities.” Washington Post, 21 Sept. 2015; Bichao, Sergio. “How The Testing Craze Scandalized Woodbridge Schools and Cheated Kids Out Of Learning.” MyCentralJersey.com; Martinez, Aaron, and Lindsey Anderson. “5 Educators Arrested in EPISD Scheme.” El Paso Times, 27 Apr. 2016.
  579. White House. “Remarks of President Barack Obama—Address to Joint Session of Congress,” 24 Feb. 2009, www.whitehouse.gov/video/EVR022409/#transcript.
  580. Ibid.
  581. US Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. “Median Weekly Earnings in 2014 Dollars of People 25 Years and Older, by Educational Attainment and Gender, 1979–2014” (noting for those with “some college or associate degree,” wages fell from a peak of $1,000 median weekly to $872 by 2014, and for women from a high of $723 in 2004 to $661 by 2014 in adjusted dollars).
  582. Author’s calculations based on data from NCES Digest, on-line edition, Table 303.70, various years (total undergrad fall enrollment in degree-granting postsecondary institutions).
  583. Ibid.
  584. US Senate, Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions Committee. “Emerging Risk?” An Overview of Growth, Spending, Student Debt and Unanswered Questions in For-Profit Higher Education,” 24 June 2010, p. 1, www.help.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/For-Profit%20Emerging%20Risk%20Report1.pdf.
  585. Ibid., p. 3 (citing Dept. of Education Analysis); see also for a comprehensive list of reports on the subject, all reaching similar conclusions, National Conference of State Legislatures. “For-Profit Colleges and Universities.” July 2013, www.ncsl.org/research/education/for-profit-colleges-and-universities.aspx.
  586. Dayen, David. “This is America’s Worst College: Screwed-Over Corinthian College Students Get Screwed Again by So-Called Debt Relief.” Salon, 9 June 2015, www.salon.com/2015/06/09/this_is_americas_worst_college_screwed_over_corinthian_college_students_get_screwed_again_by_so_called_debt_relief/.
  587. See supra notes 43–44 (noting that 18,256 were enrolled in for-profit colleges in 1970, and 106,397 in 1980, with the vast increase coming in 1990–2010).
  588. University of California. “UC Merced Freshman Admission Profile,” admission.universityofcalifornia.edu/campuses/merced/freshman-profile/index.html; University of California, Berkeley, Office of Undergraduate Admissions. “Student Profile,” admissions.berkeley.edu/studentprofile; UCLA, Office of Analysis and Information Management, www.aim.ucla.edu/admissions.aspx.
  589. National Assessment of Educational Progress, Institute of Education Sciences, National Center for Education Statistics. “First-Year Undergraduate Remedial Coursetaking: 1999–2000, 2003–04, 2007–08,” Jan. 2013, pp. 1–2, nces.ed.gov/pubs2013/2013013.pdf. Students requiring remedial education are taken as “unprepared” for our purposes.
  590. National Center for Education Statistics. “Characteristics of Postsecondary Faculty,” nces.ed.gov/programs/coe/pdf/Indicator_CSC/COE_csc_2013_04.pdf; American Association of University Professors. “Background Facts on Contingent Faculty,” www.aaup.org/issues/contingency/background-facts; see also www.aaup.org/sites/default/files/files/2013%20Salary%20Survey%20Tables%20and%20Figures/Figure%201.pdf (for historical data through 2011).
  591. French, Laurie. “The Forever Professors: Academics Who Don’t Retire Are Greedy, Selfish and Bad for Students.” Chronicle of Higher Education, 14 Nov. 2014, chronicle.com/article/Retire-Already-/149965/?cid=at&utm_source=at&utm_medium=en; Williams June, Audrey. “Aging Professors Create a Faculty Bottleneck,” Chronicle of Higher Education, 18 Mar. 2012, chronicle.com/article/Professors-Are-Graying-and/131226/ (noting a doubling of faculty aged sixty-five or older between 2000 and 2011).
  592. US Federal Reserve System, Board of Governors. “Consumer Credit—G.19,” www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g19/Current/.
  593. FRED, SLOAS; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. “Consumer Credit—G.19.” Statistical Releases and Historical Data, August 2016, www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g19/current/.
  594. Roeder, Oliver, et al. “What Caused the Crime Decline?” Brennan Center for Justice at New York University of Law, 2015, p. 3, www.brennancenter.org/sites/default/files/publications/What_Caused_The_Crime_Decline.pdf. The Brennan Center refers to “consumer confidence,” which is highly correlated with economic growth, or at least its perception.
  595. Ibid., p. 1.
  596. Ibid., table 3.
  597. Bureau of Justice Statistics. “Estimated number of persons under correctional supervision in the United States, 1980–2014.” Total Correctional Population, 2016, www.bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=kfdetail&iid=487; US Census. “Annual Estimates of the Population for the United States, Regions, States, and Puerto Rico: April 1, 2000 to July 1, 2007 (NST-EST2007-01).” National Table, 2007, www.census.gov/popest/data/historical/2000s/vintage_2007/; author’s calculations.
  598. Vargas, Ricardo. “The anti-drug policy, aerial spraying of illicit crops and their social, environmental and political impacts in Colombia.” Journal of Drug Issues, vol. 32, no. 1 (2002): 11–60. The Clinton program was known as “Plan Colombia” and well reported at the time.
  599. Langton, Lynn, and Donald Farole, Jr. “State Public Defender Programs, 2007”; US Department of Justice, Office of Justice Programs, Bureau of Justice Statistics. Special Report. Sept. 2010, www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/spdp07.pdf; US Department of Justice, Office of Justice Programs. “Public Defender Offices Nationwide Received Nearly 5.6 Million Indigent Defense Cases in 2007,” 16 Sept. 2010, ojp.gov/newsroom/pressreleases/2010/BJS10122.htm. Contractors and pro bono attorneys provide additional services, but they cannot be relied on as the core of public defense. For a good overview, see Justice Policy Institute. “System Overload: The Costs of Under-Resourcing Public Defense.” July 2011, www.justicepolicy.org/uploads/justicepolicy/documents/system_overload_final.pdf.
  600. Constitution of the United States. Sixth and Fourteenth Amendments; Gideon v. Wainwright, 372 US 335 (1963).
  601. Roeder, p. 56 et seq.
  602. Infra note 62 and the prison and associated note for this chapter; Institute for Criminal Policy Research. “World Prison Brief”; CIA World Factbook.
  603. US Department of Justice, Office of Justice Programs, Bureau of Justice Statistics. “Correctional Populations in the United States, 2014,” table 1, www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/cpus14.pdf (rev. Jan. 21, 2016); US Census, Population Division, Dec. 2015, https://factfinder.census.gov/faces/tableservices/jsf/productview.xhtml.
  604. Ibid., p. 5 (DoJ).
  605. US Department of Justice, Office of Justice Programs, Bureau of Justice Statistics. “Prisoners in 2014,” Sept. 2015, table 8; see also US Government Accountability Office. “Growing Inmate Crowding Negatively Affects Inmates, Staff, and Infrastructure,” Sept. 2012 (for historical data).
  606. Henrichson, Christian and Ruth Delaney. “The Price of Prisons: What Incarceration Costs Taxpayers.” Vera Institute for Justice. Updated 20 July 2012, pp. 7–8, www.vera.org/sites/default/files/resources/downloads/price-of-prisons-updated-version-021914.pdf.
  607. California State Legislature, Legislative Analyst’s Office. “How Much Does It Cost to Incarcerate an Inmate?” www.lao.ca.gov/PolicyAreas/CJ/6_cj_inmatecost (citing figures for 2008–2009).
  608. Federal Register. “Annual Determination of Average Cost of Incarceration” (in 2014), 9 Sept. 2015, www.federalregister.gov/articles/2015/03/09/2015-05437/annual-determination-of-average-cost-of-incarceration.
  609. FRED, G160121A027NBEA. FRED’s original source is BEA, NIPA table 3.15.
  610. University of California, “Budget for Current Operations 2015–16,” appendix 1 (Nov. 2014); State of California, “California State Budget 2015–16,” pp. 22, 33 (2015).
  611. Ollove, Michael. “Ex-Felons Are About to Get Health Coverage.” The Pew Charitable Trusts, 5 Apr. 2013, www.pewtrusts.org/en/research-and-analysis/blogs/stateline/2013/04/05/exfelons-are-about-to-get-health-coverage.
  612. US Department of Justice, Office of Justice Programs, Bureau of Justice Statistics. “Prisoners in 2014,” p. 15; see also National Association for the Advancement of Colored People. “Criminal Justice Fact Sheet,” www.naacp.org/pages/criminal-justice-fact-sheet.
    Chapter 15: The Wages of Sin
  613. US Congress, Congressional Budget Office. “Trends in Family Wealth, 1989–2013,” 18 Aug. 2016, p. 2.
  614. Hughes, Robert. “Brideshead Redecorated.” Time, 11 Nov. 1985.
  615. Appelbaum, Binyamin. “Outspoken Fed Official Frets About Following Japan’s Path.” New York Times, 4 May 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/05/05/upshot/outspoken-fed-official-frets-about-following-japans-path.html?mabReward=A3&action=click&pgtype=Homepage&_r=0.
  616. US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. National Income and Product Accounts Gross Domestic Product: Second Quarter 2016. Current releases available at: http://bea.gov/newsreleases/national/GDP/GDPnewsrelease.htm (accessed here October 10, 2016).
  617. FRED, A939RX0Q048SBEA (BEA); author’s calculations.
  618. Iritani, Evelyn. “Great Idea but Don’t Quote Him.” Los Angeles Times, 9 Sept. 2004, articles.latimes.com/2004/sep/09/business/fi-deng9/2; Bao Tong. “How Deng Xiaoping Helped Create a Corrupt China.” New York Times, 3 June 2015, www.nytimes.com/2015/06/04/opinion/bao-tong-how-deng-xiaoping-helped-create-a-corrupt-china.html?_r=0.
  619. Iritani.
  620. Congressional Budget Office. “Trends in Family Wealth, 1989 to 2013.” 2016, www.cbo.gov/publication/51846, underlying tables; author’s calculations.
  621. “Intergenerational Justice in Aging Societies: A Cross-National Comparison of 29 OECD Countries.” Bertelsmann Stiftung. Sustainable Governance Indicators. p. 6 et seq., news.sgi-network.org/uploads/tx_amsgistudies/Intergenerational_Justice_OECD.pdf.
  622. US Census. Current Population Survey, 2014. Historical Poverty table 3 and p. 12.
  623. Ibid.
  624. Congressional Budget Office. “Trends in Family Wealth, 1989 to 2013.”
  625. BLS, table A-15, U-3 measure, http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.t15.htm; Bureau of Labor Statistics. “How the Government Measures Unemployment,” www.bls.gov/cps/cps_htgm.htm.
  626. “About.” Bernie Sanders’s Senate website, www.sanders.senate.gov/about; Ronayne, Kathleen. “Sanders Declares as Democrat in NH Primary.” Burlington Free Press, 5 Nov. 2015, www.burlingtonfreepress.com/story/news/local/2015/11/05/sanders-declares-democrat-nh-primary/75242938/. Sanders may ultimately change his registration to Democrat on a permanent basis, but his homepage as of the first half of 2016 continued to mention his status as an independent.
  627. BLS, table A-15, U-6 definition, www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.t15.htm.
  628. FRED, UNRATE, UEMPMEAN, U6RATE (BEA); author’s calculations.
  629. Katz, Lawrence F., and Alan B. Krueger. “The Rise and Nature of Alternative Work Arrangements in the United States, 1995–2015.” Working Paper. 29 Mar. 2016, p. 7, revised September 13, 2016.
  630. With apologies to Robert Hughes on this.
  631. Bauerlein, David. “Automakers’ Drive into Southeast Misses Florida: Car Companies, Attracted by Incentives, Invest $6 Billion to Build Plants in Other Southeast States.” Jacksonville.com, 8 Nov. 2011, jacksonville.com/news/florida/2011-11-08/story/automakers-drive-southeast-misses-florida#.
  632. Costa, Daniel. “The Immigration Innovation (I2) Act of 2013.” Economic Policy Institute. 27 Feb. 2013, www.epi.org/publication/immigration-innovation-i2-act-2013/; US Citizenship and Immigration Services. “H-1B Fiscal Year (FY) 2017 Cap Season.” www.uscis.gov/working-united-states/temporary-workers/h-1b-specialty-occupations-and-fashion-models/h-1b-fiscal-year-fy-2017-cap-season#count.
  633. “The Lesson of Zoe Baird.” New York Times, Opinion, 23 Jan. 1993, www.nytimes.com/1993/01/23/opinion/the-lesson-of-zoe-baird.html; “Addressing Nannygate.” New York Times, Opinion, 30 Mar. 1994, www.nytimes.com/1994/03/30/opinion/addressing-nannygate.html; Johnston, David. “Clinton’s Choice for Justice Dept. Hired Illegal Aliens for Household.” New York Times, 14 Jan. 1993, www.nytimes.com/1993/01/14/us/clinton-s-choice-for-justice-dept-hired-illegal-aliens-for-household.html; Wingert, Pat. “Nannygate II: A Women’s Backlash?” Newsweek, 14 Feb. 1993, www.newsweek.com/nannygate-ii-womens-backlash-195214.
  634. The CEA provides a good overview of market concentration and its effects. Council of Economic Advisors. CEA. “Benefits of Competition and Indicators of Market Power.” Apr. 2016.
  635. Trainer, David. “How Stock Buybacks Destroy Shareholder Value.” Forbes, 24 Feb. 2016; see also Lazonick, William. “Profits Without Prosperity.” Harvard Business Review, Sept. 2014.
  636. Rosenbaum, Aliza, and Rob Cox. “Big Money: Is Big Beer Begging for an Anti-Trust Probe?” The Washington Post, 6 Sept. 2009, www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2009/09/04/AR2009090404236.html. Leeb, Stephen. “Wal-Mart Fattens Up on Poor America With 25% of U.S. Grocery Sales.” Forbes. www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/2013/05/20/wal-mart-cleans-up-on-poor-america-with-25-of-u-s-grocery-sales/#31fa4f262bea (alternative metrics have 90 percent of Americans living within 10 miles of a Wal-Mart; the effect is the same).
  637. Sanders, Bernie, and Daily News Editorial Board. “Transcript: Bernie Sanders meets with News Editorial Board.” New York Daily News, Opinion, 4 Apr. 2016, www.nydailynews.com/opinion/transcript-bernie-sanders-meets-news-editorial-board-article-1.2588306.
  638. Fuglie, Keith, et al. “Rising Concentration in Agricultural Input Industries Influences New Farm Technologies.” US Department of Agriculture, 3 Dec. 2012, www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2012-december/rising-concentration-in-agricultural-input-industries-influences-new-technologies.aspx#.Vxf2yzArKM8.
    Chapter 16: The Myth of Boomer Goodness
  639. Mamet, David. The Secret Knowledge: On the Dismantling of American Culture. Penguin, e-books edition, 2001, pp. 281–282.
  640. Bradner, Eric. “Bill Clinton Spars with Black Lives Matter Protesters.” CNN, 8 Apr. 2016, www.cnn.com/2016/04/07/politics/bill-clinton-black-lives-matter-protesters/index.html.
  641. Ibid.
  642. Ibid.
  643. 570 U.S. __ 2013, Docket No. 12–96.
  644. Serwer, Adam. “Chief Justice Roberts’ Long War Against the Voting Rights Act.” Mother Jones, 27 Feb. 2013, www.motherjones.com/politics/2013/02/john-roberts-long-war-against-voting-rights-act; see also Rutenberg, Jim. “A Dream Undone.” New York Times Magazine, 29 July 2015, www.nytimes.com/2015/07/29/magazine/voting-rights-act-dream-undone.html.
  645. Howard, Cory H. “A Return to Dred Scott? How Recent Supreme Court Jurisprudence Reflects Dred Scott’s Legal Reasoning and Fails to Protect the Most Vulnerable in Today’s Society.” Faulkner Law Review, vol. 6, no. 2, 2014–2015, part V. It’s not that Shelby was a recapitulation of Dred Scott so much as the triumph of state’s rights over individual civil rights in a similar context and with similar reasoning, with what some might see as not dissimilar implications.
  646. “The Formula behind the Voting Rights Act.” New York Times, 22 Jun. 2013, www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/06/23/us/voting-rights-act-map.html; Shelby v. Holder, 570 US (2013) pp. 4–6.
  647. US Census. Census of 1980, vol. 1, May 1983, title page.
  648. City of Mobile v. Borden, 446 US 55 (1980).
  649. For a general history with pro-VRA leanings, see Leadership Conference. “History of the VRA.” www.civilrights.org/voting-rights/vra/history.html.
  650. Santos, Fernanda. “Angry Arizona Voters Demand: Why Such Long Lines at Polling Stations?” New York Times, 24 Mar. 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/03/25/us/angry-arizona-voters-demand-why-such-long-lines-at-polling-sites.html; see also for associated other questionable practices: Wigel, David. “Two Polling Places, Both Inside Police Stations.” See also Slate, 18 Mar. 2014, www.slate.com/blogs/weigel/2014/03/18/_two_polling_places_both_inside_police_stations.html; National Association for the Advancement of Colored People. “Defending Democracy: Confronting Modern Barriers to Voting Rights in America,” www.naacp.org/pages/defending-democracy.
  651. Gay Stolberg, Sheryl, and Erik Eckholm. “Virginia Governor Restores Voting Rights to Felons.” New York Times, 23 Apr. 2016, www.nytimes.com/2016/04/23/us/governor-terry-mcauliffe-virginia-voting-rights-convicted-felons.html?_r=0.
  652. Chung, Jean. “Felony Disenfranchisement: A Primer.” Sentencing Project, 10 May 2016, fig. B, www.sentencingproject.org/publications/felony-disenfranchisement-a-primer/.
  653. Public Law 92–225 (1972).
  654. Federal Election Commission. “About the FEC,” www.fec.gov/about.sthml.
  655. Buckley v. Valeo, 424 US 1 (1976).
  656. First National Bank of Boston v. Bellotti, 435 US 735, pp. 826–28 (1978) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting).
  657. Helderman, Rosalind S. “Donor Gave McDonnell and Family a Lake-House Vacation.” Washington Post, 18 Apr. 2013, www.washingtonpost.com/local/va-politics/donor-gave-mcdonnell-and-family-a-lake-house-vacation/2013/04/18/7573321c-a76f-11e2-8302-3c7e0ea97057_story.html.
  658. Planned Parenthood v. Casey, 505 US 833 (1992), pp. 874–77. Whole Woman’s Health v. Hellerstedt kept the “undue burdens” test but drew a modest line toward a more permissive interpretation thereof. 579 US (2016).
  659. Deprez, Esmé E. “Abortion Clinics Close at Record Pace After States Tighten Rules.” Bloomberg, 3 Sept. 2013, www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-09-03/abortion-clinics-close-at-record-pace-after-states-tighten-rules. For a particularly bizarre example of the renewed debate over abortion, there is, of course, the example of Trump. Krieg, Gregory. “Donald Trump’s 3 Positions on Abortion in 3 Hours.” CNN, 31 Mar. 2016, www.cnn.com/2016/03/30/politics/donald-trump-abortion-positions/index.html.
  660. White House, Council of Economic Advisors. Issue Brief. “Gender Pay Gap: Recent Trends and Explanations,” April 2015, p. 1, www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/docs/equal_pay_issue_brief_final.pdf.
  661. Cooper, Rob. “Inside Apple’s Chinese ‘Sweatshop’ Factory Where Workers Are Paid Just £1.12 Per Hour to Produce iPhones and iPads for the West.” Daily Mail, 25 Jan. 2013, http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-2103798/Revealed-Inside-Apples-Chinese-sweatshop-factory-workers-paid-just-1-12-hour.html (based on reporting originally conducted by Nightline).
  662. Hillenbrand. 2015 Annual Report, p. 3, s1.q4cdn.com/966021326/files/doc_financials/annual/hillenbrand-ar-2015.pdf.
  663. Obergefell v. Hodges, 135 S. Ct. 2584 (2015); Wang, Wendy. “The Rise of Intermarriage: Rates, Characteristics Vary by Race and Gender.” Pew Research Center, 16 Feb. 2012, pp. 33–40, www.pewsocialtrends.org/files/2012/02/SDT-Intermarriage-II.pdf; Loving v. Virginia, 388 U.S. 1 (1967).
  664. “Changing Attitudes on Gay Marriage.” Pew Research Center, 12 May 2016, sec. 1; “Support for Same-Sex Marriage at Record High, but Key Segments Remain Opposed.” Pew Research Center, 8 June 2015, p. 3.
  665. Crabtree, Steve. “Gallup Brain: Strom Thurmond and the 1948 Election.” Gallup, 17 Dec. 2002, www.gallup.com/poll/7444/gallup-brain-strom-thurmond-1948-election.aspx; National Defense Research Institute. “Sexual Orientation and U.S. Military Personnel Policy: Options and Assessment.” Rand Corporation, 1993, p. 191 et seq.
  666. Public Law 103-160, subtitle G, §654(a).15 (1993).
  667. Goldwater, Barry M. “Ban on Gays Is Senseless Attempt to Stall the Inevitable.” Carnegie Mellon University, www.cs.cmu.edu/afs/cs/usr/scotts/bulgarians/barry-goldwater.html (selections from Goldwater’s commentary in the New York Times and the Washington Post); “Goldwater Backs Gay Troops.” New York Times, 11 June 1993.
  668. “More Support for Gun Rights, Gay Marriage Than in 2004, 2008.” Pew Research Center for the People & the Press, 25 Apr. 2012, p. 5, www.people-press.org/files/legacy-pdf/4-25-12%20Social%20Issues.pdf.
  669. Americans with Disabilities Act Amendments Act of 2008. 42 USC §§ 12102.1-2(A) (2009).
  670. For an exemplar ad for Rascal reimbursement, see e.g., www.localcommunities.org/servlet/lc_procserv/dbpage=page&mode=display&gid=01331001151093379080423861
  671. California Constitution, art. 1, sec. 1.
  672. Olmstead v. United States, 277 U.S. 438 (1928) (Brandeis, J., dissenting).
  673. Ibid.
  674. Gellman, Barton, and Ashton Soltani. “NSA Infiltrates Links to Yahoo, Google Data Centers Worldwide, Snowden Documents Says.” Washington Post, 30 Oct. 2013, washingtonpost.com/world/national-security/nsa-infiltrates-links-to-yahoo-google-data-centers-worldwide-snowden-documents-say/2013/10/30/e51d661e-4166-11e3-8b74-d89d714ca4dd_story.html.
  675. Gugliotta Guy, and Juliet Eilperin. “Tough Response Appeals to Clinton Critics.” Washington Post, 21 Aug. 1998, A17, www.washingtonpost.com/wp-srv/politics/special/clinton/stories/react082198.htm. Most senators did not question Clinton’s timing, but some did, and I do—at least in context with the tardiness of his other interventions.
  676. Goldberg, Jeffrey. “The Obama Doctrine: The U.S. President Talks Through His Hardest Decisions About America’s Role in the World.” Atlantic, Apr. 2016, www.theatlantic.com/magazine/archive/2016/04/the-obama-doctrine/471525/.
    Chapter 17: Price Tags and Prescriptions
  677. Psalm 51:5 (King James Bible).
  678. Puentes, Robert. et al. “A New Alignment: Strengthening America’s Commitment to Passenger Rail.” Metropolitan Policy Program at Brookings. 1 Mar. 2013, pp. 7–11, www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/passenger-rail-puentes-tomer.pdf. The Northeast Corridor receives almost no state support, unlike less intensively used lines, and runs a net operating profit (discounting depreciation).
  679. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau. “Private Student Loans,” 29 Aug. 2012, files.consumerfinance.gov/f/201207_cfpb_Reports_Private-Student-Loans.pdf.
  680. US Department of Education. Federal Student Aid, “Interest Rates for New Direct Loans,” studentaid.ed.gov/sa/about/announcements/interest-rate.
  681. Psalm 90:10 (King James Bible). “Fourscore,” by the way, is very close to the actual American life expectancy.
  682. OECD. “How Does Sweden Compare?” Health Statistics 2014, www.oecd.org/els/health-systems/Briefing-Note-SWEDEN-2014.pdf.
  683. Pew Research Center. “Most Say Government Policies Since Recession Have Done Little to Help Middle Class, Poor: ‘Partial’ Recovery Seen in Jobs, Household Incomes,” 4 Mar. 2015, www.people-press.org/files/2015/03/03-04-15-Economy-release.pdf.
  684. US Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service. “2014 Data Book.” 1 Oct. 2013 to 30 Sept. 2014, table 9.b, www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/14databk.pdf.
  685. Entin, Stephen J. “President Obama’s Capital Gains Tax Proposals: Bad for the Economy and the Budget.” Tax Foundation, 21 Jan 2015, taxfoundation.org/blog/president-obama-s-capital-gains-tax-proposals-bad-economy-and-budget. The Tax Foundation has its own axes to grind, but is almost certainly correct on this point based on IRS data.
  686. Congressional Budget Office, “The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013.” June 2016. See the supplementary data associated with this report and Chapter 9 of this book. There was a meaningful change in federal tax regimes for the richest Americans from 2012 to 2013, and some filers responded by accelerating income into 2012, which may understate the skew for 2013. Nevertheless, 2013 is the latest tax data available and the general distribution of income and taxes over the recent past shows the same dynamic.
  687. US Department of the Treasury, “FY 2015 Gift Contributions to Reduce Debt Held by the Public.” http://www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/gift/gift_2015.htm.
  688. US Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service. “Tax Gap Estimates for Tax Years 2008–2010,” Apr. 2016, www.irs.gov/PUP/newsroom/tax%20gap%20estimates%20for%202008%20through%202010.pdf. The IRS does not conduct “tax gap” analyses on a regular basis; these were the most recent figures—current figures are probably higher due to a slightly larger economy and inflation.
  689. Myles, Udland. “US Companies Don’t Pay What They’re Supposed To in Taxes—And It’s Getting Worse.” Business Insider, 18 Oct. 2015, www.businessinsider.com/us-company-effective-tax-rate-below-statutory-rate-2015-10.
  690. Pearson, Rich, and Kim Geiger. “Illinois Supreme Court Rules Landmark Pension Law Unconstitutional.” Chicago Tribune, www.chicagotribune.com/ct-illinois-pension-law-court-ruling-20150508-story.html.
  691. Freeland, Will. “Nonpayers of Federal Taxes and Net Beneficiaries of Federal Spending.” Tax Foundation, taxfoundation.org/blog/nonpayers-federal-taxes-and-net-beneficiaries-federal-spending; author’s own calculations regarding rebates and social consumption based on CBO analyses from the series “Distribution of Major Tax Expenditures” and “Distribution of Household Income and Federal Tax” series from various years.
  692. Taylor, Paul, et al. “Once Again, the Future Ain’t What It Used to Be.” Pew Research Center, 2 May 2006, p. 2, www.pewsocialtrends.org/files/2010/10/BetterOff.pdf. Half of adults think children generally will do worse, though a declining majority think their children will do better—another instance of wishful thinking.
    Afterword
  693. Ortega y Gasset, Juan. The Revolt of the Masses. W. W. Norton, New York: 1993 (3d ed.) at 93. The philosopher believed that a generation lasted about thirty years, the first half practicing revolution and the second half preserving its legacy. The Boomers are still upending the system forty years on, distinct from both their predecessors and their eventual successors, and in this sense are still pretty revolutionary. Ibid. at fn. 1.
  694. Schmitt, Carl. The Concept of the Political. University of Chicago Press, 15 May 2007 (generally).
  695. Gabler, Neal. “The Secret Shame of the Middle-Class Americans: Nearly Half of Americans Would Have Trouble Finding $400 to Pay for an Emergency. I’m One of Them.” Atlantic, May 2016. The Atlantic article serves as the source for most of the material quoted about Gabler, with some exceptions including his education and age (he was born 1950), facts reported in several profiles including one in the Great Lakes Review. E.g., Root, Robert L., “GLR Interview: Neal Gabler,” Great Lakes Review, vol. 11, no. 11 (Spring 1985), pp. 32–38.
  696. US Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service. “Social Security Benefits Eligible for the Federal Payment Levy Program,” www.irs.gov/individuals/social-security-benefits-eligible-for-the-federal-payment-levy-program.

Pardons necessarily favored those who had “dodged up,” who tended to be white and middle-class. People who had “dodged down” by committing crimes continued to pay the price. With the mainstream Boomers in the clear, questions about lingering domestic injustice, like questions of foreign reparations, evaporated. As for those who had served overseas, there was no warm welcome. Some were greeted by protests, and all faced a dysfunctional veterans’ benefits system that, having succeeded after World War II, slowly starved as the Boomer machine prioritized other programs. But for the vast majority of Boomers who stayed home, the Vietnam era concluded in 1977. They had gotten cleanly away. The lessons of consequence-free sociopathy would not be forgotten.